RURAL BANKING IN INDIA
Submitted in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the award of degree Of
MBA In
FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT
Submitted By:
VARUN TRICHAL 511227243
DEPARTMENT OF MANAGEMENT
SIKKIM MANIPAL UNIVERSITY SIKKIM
1
DECLARATION
I hereby declare that the project entitled “Rural Banking in India” which is being submitted in partial fulfilment of the requirement for the award of the Degree of Master in Business istration to “SIKKIM MANIPAL UNIVERSITY, SIKKIM” is an authentic record of our own work done under the guidance of Mr.Atul Dubey, Department of Management, SIKKIM MANIPAL UNIVERSITY, SIKKIM. The matter reported in this project has not been submitted earlier for the award of any other degree.
Mr. Atul Dubey HOD OF DEPARTMENT
Varun Trichal STUDENT NAME
2
ACKNOWLEDGEMENT
I sincerely express indebtedness to esteemed and revered guide “Ms. Deepti Tarani”, for her invaluable guidance, supervision and encouragement throughout the work. Without her kind patronage and guidance, the project would not have taken shape.
I take this opportunity to express deep sense of gratitude to “Mr. Atul Dubey”, Head of Management Studies, for his encouragement and kind approval. We would like to express our sincere regards to him for advice and counseling from time to time.
I owe sincere thanks to all the lecturers in “Rural Banking in India” for their advice and counseling time to time.
Varun Trichal
3
BONAFIDE CERTIFICATE
Certified that this Project Report titled “Rural Banking in India” is the Bonafied work Of “Varun Trichal” who carried out the project work under my supervision.
SIGNATURE: SIGNATURE: HEAD OF THE DEPARTMENT IN CHARGE
FACULTY
4
ABSTRACT Summary of Project Rural banking in India has been the subject of study Survey Committee Report in 1954, literally thousands of reports have examined and investigated the problems relating to the credit delivery for agriculture and rural area. Latest magnum opus on the subject is the National Agricultural Credit Review report 2000. The Expert Committee on Rural Credit (Chairman: Professor V.S.Vyas) submitted its report in 2002.One more High Power Committee headed by Professor Vyas set up by the Reserve Bank of India recently to review and advice on improving credit delivery to agriculture has also given its report. Financial liberalization after 1991 decimated the formal system of institutional credit in rural India. It represented a clear and explicit reversal of the policy of social and development banking, such as it was, and contributed in no small way to the extreme deprivation and distress of which the rural poor in India have been victims over the last decade. Rural credit has been a laboratory for various policies, initiatives, investigations and improvements since 1955.The first major
strategy
adopted
for
improving
rural
credit
delivery
was
the
institutionalization of the credit delivery system with the cooperative as the primary channels. Various approaches have been adopted for improving rural credit from time to time. It was felt that project lending will revolutionize rural credit. This was followed by area approach and extensionbased schemes and then the lead bank scheme providing for forward and backward linkages and the scheme of linking banks to Primary Agricultural Credit Societies and the linkage of bank to microfinance institutions.
To echo the thoughts of C.K. Prahalad, the “bottom of the pyramid” segments will be the growth drivers of the future – this is certainly being 5
borne out by the market revolution that is taking place in India’s villages. The
Narasimham
committee
on
rural
credit
recommended
the
establishment of Regional Rural Banks (RRBs) in meeting the needs of rural areas. The purpose of this essay is not to evaluate the
rural
credit
policy
of
the
United
Progressive
Alliance
government.
Nevertheless, it is clear that if any government is seriously to address the crisis in rural banking, it must reaffirm the commitment of the state to the policy of social and development banking, and reaffirm the part played by the credit system in redistribution and poverty alleviation. The objective of the study is to study marketing of rural banking in India and to study comparative marketing of rural and urban banking in India. Research in common parlance refers to a search for knowledge. Descriptive research design studies are those studies, which are concerned with describing the character of a group. The researcher makes a plan of the study his research work. The study was based on questionnaire method. The primary data are those, which are collected a fresh and for the first time happen to be original in character. Secondary data are those which have already been collected by someone else and which have already been ed through the stratified process. It has collected through the books, journals & Internet.
RRBs' performance in respect of some important indicators was certainly better than that of commercial banks or even cooperatives. RRBs have also performed better in of providing loans to small and retail traders and petty non-farm rural activities. In recent years, they have taken a leading role in financing Self-Help Groups (SHGs) and other microcredit institutions and linking such groups with the formal credit sector. RRBs should really be strengthened and provided with more resources with which they can undertake more of these important activities. And most certainly they should be kept apart from a profit-oriented corporate motivation that would reduce their capacity to provide much needed financial services to the rural areas, including to agriculture. 6
The number of rural branches should be increased rather than reduced; they should be encouraged to develop more sophisticated methods of credit delivery to meet the changing needs of farming; and most of all, there should be greater coordination between district planning authorities, Panchayati raj institutions and the banks operating in rural areas. Only then will the RRBs fulfill the promise that is so essential for rural development.
7
REFERENCE Books:
Aaker (1991) Building Strong Brands; New York: Free Press
Chatterjee, Jauchius, Kaas and Satpathy no. 1, (2002): 'Revving up auto branding', McKinsey Quarterly.
David. A. Aaker, V.Kumar & George S. Day, (2001) Descriptive Research: Marketing Research, Seventh Edition, pp 17
Saxena,
Rajan.
(2003):’Marketing
Management’
Tata
Mcgraw-Hill
Publishing Company Limited. New Delhi
Sontakki, C.N. (1997):’Marketing Management’ Kayali Publisher., New Delhi.
Kotler, Philip. (1999):’Marketing Management’ Prentice Hall of India Pvt. Ltd., New Delhi.
Kothari, C.R (2001):’Research Methodology’, Vishwa Publication., New Delhi
Sharma,D.D(2002):’Marketing Research’, Sultan Chand Sons, New Delhi
Magazines:
Business Today
Business Week.
Business World
Newspapers
Economic Times
The Hindu
Times of India
8
QUESTIONNAIRE NAME –
SEX -
AGE –
DESIGNATION –
Dear sir/madam, 1) Central Scheme to provide Interest Subsidy for the period of moratorium on loans taken by farmer from economically weaker sections from schedule banks under the loan scheme of the Indian Banks Association? □ To great extent □ To some extent □ To very little extent 2) To what extent is Sales Promotions have been used by banker to increase sales in the short term? □ Completely □ Partially □ Nil 3) Does your marketing policy of bank have focus marketing on agro- sector? □ strongly agree □ Agree □ Disagree □ strongly disagree □ can’t say
9
4) Multiple ‘basic’ financial services and loan gateway is product marketing of the bank?
□ Yes
□ No
5) Devised to ensure usage as well as profitability Quantity discounts, and ease in payment modes is pricing marketing of the bank?
□ Yes
□ No
6) Comprehensive offering of different services is placement marketing of the bank? □ Traditional
□ Modern
7) Collaborating with NGO’s to development Knowledge marketing of the bank
□ Yes
□ No
10
INDEX 1. INTRODUCTION 2. BANKING POLICY IN RURAL INDIA 3. DISTRIBUTION CHANNEL OF RURAL BANKING 4. MARKETING STRATEGIES OF RURAL BANKING PLAYERS IN INDIA 5. AN ICT STRUCTURE FOR RURAL BANKING ENABLEMENT 6. OBJECTIVE OF THE STUDY 7. RESEARCH METHODOLOGY 8. DATA ANALYSIS AND INTERPRETATION 9. CONCLUSION 10. BIBLIOGRAPHY 11. ANNEXURE
11
INTRODUCTION
12
INTRODUCTION Rural banking in India has been the subject of study Survey Committee Report in 1954, literally thousands of reports have examined and investigated the problems relating to the credit delivery for agriculture and rural area. Latest magnum opus on the subject is the National Agricultural Credit Review report 2000. The Expert Committee on Rural Credit (Chairman: Professor V.S.Vyas) submitted its report in 2002.One more High Power Committee headed by Professor Vyas set up by the Reserve Bank of India recently to review and advice on improving credit delivery to agriculture has also given its report. As the majority of the Indian population lives in rural areas, there is an urgent need to deliver citizen services to them in a cost effective way with assured quality. This involves mainly the following: 1. Enabling the ready access at the place of the villagers. 2. Reducing transaction cost to make the services affordable. 3. Reduction in delays. 4. Improving the quality of services available. The criticality of this need may be seen from the fact that even with concerted and extensive attempts to meet the credit needs of the farmers for agricultural operations etc., informal agencies including money lenders are currently providing substantial portion of the total credit to this sector. Besides, the agricultural credit flows themselves are inadequate and the gross capital formation can be improved only if substantial amount of investment funds flow to the rural areas in the form of credit. Likewise, there is also a need to provide market information, extension services, marketing and government and other public services to the people in a cost-effective manner. For achieving financial inclusion and economic growth, the ICT can play an important role by increasing effective access and improving delivery and governance in banking services. Against this background, the key issue is how technology can be harnessed for improving the efficacy of the credit delivery and for the minimization of the transaction costs involved, for ensuring that bank credit actually increases and promotes productive capital formation and investment in rural areas and helps address the critical problem of the rural-urban service divide.
13
The Rural Economy Financial liberalization after 1991 decimated the formal system of institutional credit in rural India. It represented a clear and explicit reversal of the policy of social and development banking, such as it was, and contributed in no small way to the extreme deprivation and distress of which the rural poor in India have been victims over the last decade. This paper examines the impact of changes in banking policy and structure on the rural economy, and on the rural poor in particular. Financial liberalization is a crucial component of the programmes of economic reforms that are being imposed on the people of less-developed countries. The demand that financial markets be liberalized quickly is high on the agenda of imperialism; in India as well, advocates of economic “reform” see financial liberalization as being at the core of structural adjustment. There are many components of the package of reforms associated with financial liberalization in India. Chandrasekhar and Ghosh (2002) classify the policies of financial liberalization in India into three types: first, policies to curtail government intervention in the allocation of credit, secondly, policies to dismantle the public sector and foster private banking, and thirdly, polices to lower capital controls on the Indian banking system. It is well known that the burden of indebtedness in rural India is very great, and that despite major structural changes in credit institutions and forms of rural credit in the post-Independence period, the exploitation of the rural masses in the credit market is one of the most pervasive and persistent features of rural life in India. Rural households need credit for a variety of reasons. They need credit to meet short-term requirements of working capital and for long-term investment in agriculture and other income-bearing activities. Agricultural and non-agricultural activities in rural areas typically are seasonal, and households need credit to smoothen out seasonal fluctuations in earnings and expenditure. Rural households, particularly those vulnerable to what appear to others to be minor shocks with respect to income and expenditure, need credit as an insurance against risk. In a society that has no law of free, compulsory and universal school education, no arrangements for free and universal preventive and curative health care, a weak system for the public distribution of food and very few general social security programmes, rural households need credit for different types of consumption. These include expenditure on food, housing, health and education. In the Indian context, another important purpose of borrowing is to meet expenses on a variety of social obligations and rituals.
14
If these credit needs of the poor are to be met, rural households need access to credit institutions that provide them a range of financial services, provide credit at reasonable rates of interest and provide loans that are unencumbered by extra-economic provisions and obligations. Historically, there have been four major problems with respect to the supply of credit to the Indian countryside. First, the supply of formal sector credit to the countryside as a whole has been inadequate. Secondly, rural credit markets in India themselves have been very imperfect and fragmented. Thirdly, as the foregoing suggests, the distribution of formal sector credit has been unequal, particularly with respect to region and class, caste and gender in the countryside. Formal sector credit needs specially to reach backward areas, income-poor households, people of the oppressed castes and tribes, and women. Fourthly, the major source of credit to rural households, particularly incomepoor working households, has been the informal sector. Informal sector loans typically are advanced at very high rates of interest. Further, the and conditions attached to these loans have given rise to an elaborate structure of coercion – economic and extra-economic – in the countryside. That these constitute what may be called the “problem of rural credit” has been well recognized; recognized, in fact, in official evaluations and scholarship since the end of the nineteenth century. Given the issues involved, the declared objectives of public policy with regard to rural credit in the post-Independence period were, in the words of a former Governor of the Reserve Bank of India, “to ensure that sufficient and timely credit, at reasonable rates of interest, is made available to as large a segment of the rural population as possible” (Rangarajan 1996, p. 288). The policy instruments to achieve these objectives were to be, first, the expansion of the institutional structure of formal-sector lending institutions; secondly, directed lending, and thirdly, concessional or subsidized credit (ibid.). Public policy was thus aimed not only at meeting rural credit needs but also at pushing out the informal sector and the exploitation to which it subjected borrowers. Rural credit policy in India envisaged the provision of a range of credit services, including longterm and short-term credit and large-scale and small-scale loans to rural households.
15
BANKING POLICY IN RURAL INDIA
16
BANKING POLICY IN RURAL INDIA BANKING POLICY IN RURAL INDIA: 1969 TO THE PRESENT The period from 1969 to the present can be characterised as representing, broadly speaking, three phases in banking policy vis-à-vis the Indian countryside. The first was the period following the nationalization of India’s 14 major commercial banks in 1969. This was also the early phase of the ‘green revolution’ in rural India, and one of the objectives of the nationalization of banks was for the state to gain access to new liquidity, particularly among rich farmers, in the countryside. The declared objectives of the new policy with respect to rural banking - what came to be known as “social and development banking” - were (i) to provide banking services in previously unbanked or under-banked rural areas; (ii) to provide substantial credit to specific activities, including agriculture and cottage industries; and (iii) to provide credit to certain disadvantaged groups such as, for example, Dalit and Scheduled Tribe households
The introduction of social and development banking policy entailed a radical shift from prevalent practice in respect of the objective and functioning of commercial banks. An important feature of the policy of social and development banking was that it recast completely the role of commercial banks in rural banking. Prior to 1969, the countryside was not considered to be the problem of commercial banks.5 It was only after 1969 that a multi-institutional approach to credit provision in the countryside became policy, with commercial banks, Regional Rural Banks and cooperative institutions establishing wide geographical and functional reach in the Indian countryside. The Reserve Bank of India (RBI) issued specific directives with respect to social and development banking. These included setting targets for the expansion of rural branches, imposing ceilings on interest rates, and setting guidelines for the sectoral allocation of credit. Rural credit was an important component of the ‘green revolution’ package; the first post-nationalization phase of expansion in rural banking saw a substantial growth in credit advances for agriculture. Specifically, a target of 40 per cent of advances for the “priority sectors,” namely agriculture and allied activities, and small-scale and cottage industries, was set for commercial banks. Advances to the countryside increased 17
substantially, although they were, as was the green revolution itself, biased in respect of regions, crops and classes.6 The two main crops that gained from the green revolution, as is well recognized, were wheat and rice, and the application of the new technologies was primarily in the irrigated areas of the north-west and south of India, with the benefits concentrated among the richer classes of cultivators. In 1975, the Government established by ordinance and then legislation a new network of rural financial institutions called the Regional Rural Banks (RRBs), which were promoted by the Government of India, State governments and commercial banks. These were created on the basis of recommendations by a working group on commercial credit, also called the Narasimham Committee, and were intended to “combine the cooperatives’ local feel and familiarity with the business acumen of commercial banks” (Jagan Mohan, 2004, p 22).7 The number of such banks expanded rapidly, and covered 476 districts by 1987 The second phase, which began in the late 1970s and early 1980s, was a period when the rhetoric of land reform was finally discarded by the ruling classes themselves, and a period when the major instruments of official anti-poverty policy were programmes for the creation of employment. Two strategies for employment generation were envisaged, namely wage-employment through state-sponsored rural employment schemes and self-employment generation by means of loans-cum-subsidy schemes targeted at the rural poor. Thus began a period of directed credit, during which credit was directed towards “the weaker sections.” The most important new scheme of this phase was, of course, the Integrated Rural Development Programme or IRDP, a scheme for the creation of productive income-bearing assets among the poor through the allocation of subsidized credit. The IRDP was initiated in 1978-79 as a pilot project and extended to all rural blocks of the country in 1980. There is much writing on the failure of IRDP to create long-term incomebearing assets in the hands of asset-poor rural households. 8 Among the many reasons for this failure were the absence of agrarian reform and decentralized institutions of democratic government, the inadequacy of public infrastructure and public provisioning of services and the persistence of employment-insecurity and poverty in rural society. Nevertheless, the IRDP strategy did lead to a significant transfer of funds to the rural poor.
18
The second phase also involved an expansion and consolidation of the institutional infrastructure of rural banking. “Even ardent critics of India’s growth strategy,” wrote a noted scholar of India’s banking system, “would it that what the country achieved in the area of financial sector development before the present reform process began, particularly after bank nationalization, was unparalleled in financial history” (Shetty 1997, 253). After bank nationalization, as Shetty points out, there was “an unprecedented growth of commercial banking in of both geographical spread and functional reach” The third and current phase, which began in 1991, is that of liberalization. The policy objectives of this phase are encapsulated in the Report of the Committee on the Financial System, which was chaired, ironically, by the same person who recommended the establishment of Regional Rural Banks, M. Narasimham (RBI, 1991). In its very first paragraph, the report called for “a vibrant and competitive financial system…to sustain the ongoing reform in the structural aspects of the real economy.” The Committee said that redistributive objectives “should use the instrumentality of the fiscal rather than the credit system” and, accordingly, that “directed credit programmes should be phased out.” It also recommended that interest rates be deregulated, that capital adequacy norms be changed (to “compete with banks globally”), that branch licensing policy be revoked, that a new institutional structure that is “market-driven and based on profitability” be created, and that the part played by private Indian and foreign banks be enlarged. Let us make it clear that, before the 1990s, the banking system was open to much criticism, particularly of its bureaucratic failures, its insensitivity to the social and economic contexts in which it functioned, and class and regional inequalities in lending patterns. The reforms proposed in 1991, however, were not attempts to bring rural banking closer to the poor, but to cut it back altogether and throw the entire structure of social and development banking overboard.
19
DISTRIBUTION CHANNEL OF RURAL BANKING
20
Distribution Channel of Rural Banking - Multi-agency Approach to Rural Lending Rural credit has been a laboratory for various policies, initiatives, investigations and improvements since 1955.The first major strategy adopted for improving rural credit delivery was the institutionalization of the credit delivery system with the cooperative as the primary channels. The multi-agency approach to the rural credit delivery emerged with the induction of the commercial banks into the scene. In 1979, specialized institutions called Regional Rural Banks and subsequently, another breed of institutions called Local Area Banks, came on the scene. With the operationalisation of the Lead Bank Scheme, the area approach to rural lending was formalized and attempts were made to match infrastructure development with bank credit flows for ensuring development of the rural areas. The Scheme sought to give a special supply-leading role to the banking system in rural development and also to ensure access of the rural population to bank services through rural branch expansion. A multi-agency credit delivery system is in place for financing credit-based development activities, under the Lead Bank Scheme. In 1988, the Service Area Approach was also introduced as a strategy for improving the quality of rural lending. The Lead Bank Scheme Information System and Service Area Monitoring Information System (SAMIS) have also been operationalised using monitoring arrangements. The micro-finance and linkage of the banks to the self- helpgroups / NGOs and the issue of Kisan Credit Cards are among the recent developments in the area of rural lending in India. The latest policy initiatives are the enabling of the Non-bank Financial Companies and of the “correspondent “banking for increasing delivery of rural credit. The National Agricultural Credit Review Committee (NACRC) headed by Prof. A S Khusru has established that the cost of rural lending by commercial banks and cooperative banks is unsustainable and does not break even In fact, it has been sustained through cross subsidization. The two elements of the costs namely, capital costs and the current expenses are of the rural branches. Rural bank branches are such that the transaction in the rural area cannot them.
21
The experiment of having low cost institution for rural lending in the form of Regional Rural Banks also has not been successful in as much as the RRB staff expenses are required by law to be on par those of the commercial banks. Therefore, it is clear that the rural credit delivery system is not performing efficiently and in a cost effective manner. It is against this background that we position a technology based solution for improving the speed efficiency and effectiveness of the credit delivery of the rural people through the application of information technology tools and systems. We propose Model for using Information Technology for improving rural credit delivery system by reducing the cost, increasing the speed of delivery and also increasing the value addition in the service delivery and improving the ability. The National Agricultural Credit Review Committee Report documents the history, development and the status of the various important issues involved in rural credit delivery in India in great detail. It is interesting to know from this voluminous report that solutions have been advised and implemented for almost all the real as well as “perceived” problems in rural credit. Yet, this area remains a problem defying adequate solution. For example, some of the key concerns like the end-use of credit, infrastructure gaps, and the high costs of lending have been repeatedly attended to. Despite that, the delivery of credit for agriculture and rural development still remains unsatisfactory. It has been a matter of concern that the multi- institutional rural credit delivery system has not been very successful in delivering required amount of credit to agriculture and small scale industries and small and medium enterprises. i The share of bank credit for agriculture has declined from 17.6 percent in 1985 to 9.8 percent in 2002. i The institutions are in place, the systems repeatedly revamped several times on the basis of multiple committees are also in place. In spite of this, the growths of the agricultural credit in the country during the last three years have been less than the growth of credit for services and corporate sector. The value addition to the GDP by the agriculture has been low as compared to the industry sector and the services sector. The income disparities as reflected in the poverty are still a matter of serious concern.
22
Various approaches have been adopted for improving rural credit from time to time. It was felt that project lending will revolutionize rural credit. This was followed by area approach and extension- based schemes and then the lead bank scheme providing for forward and backward linkages and the scheme of linking banks to Primary Agricultural Credit Societies and the linkage of bank to microfinance institutions. Under the hypothesis that social factors like education, training and social pressures have critical bearing on the credit off-take and its productive deployment in rural areas; several attempts have been made and are being made to address them. Accordingly, the group-lending, the family approach and entrepreneurial development programme, the involvement of NGOs and voluntary agencies, the social groups and the use of self-help-groups are all being tried out for channeling adequate credit to agriculture and rural sectors. With considerable enthusiasm followed by disappointment, the cooperatives were positioned as the primary, rather the exclusive channel, for rural credit delivery for about two decades and the latest reports on the cooperatives is that, by and large, they themselves require assistance rather than being of any assistance to the farmers. Despite concerted efforts by a multitude of agencies, the agricultural credit delivery still remains a problem. The 2003 November Review of the Monetary and Credit Policy takes up this and provides for the constitution of an Advisory Committee to review the various exiting arrangements and “to suggest appropriate changes in the institutional and procedural arrangements for the smooth flow of credit to agriculture” The Policy also states that the Committee is “expected to help in capturing technological developments in the cause of improving credit delivery” [4]. Despite the large number of initiatives, the rural credit delivery system still requires improvements. Credit off-take and its quality have to increase to facilitate rural capital formation, employment and growth. The speed of loan processing should be faster and the cost of delivery should be reduced. These issues are currently relevant and important and have been identified as such in the November 2003 credit policy statement of the Reserve Bank of India as well.
23
Marketing strategies of rural banking players in India
24
To echo the thoughts of C.K. Prahalad, the “bottom of the pyramid” segments will be the growth drivers of the future – this is certainly being borne out by the market revolution that is taking place in India’s villages. The Narasimham committee on rural credit recommended the establishment of Regional Rural Banks (RRBs) in meeting the needs of rural areas. Indian mobile banking has two major segments: the urban segment and the rural segment. Celent estimates that urban mobile banking subscribers will reach 65 million by 2012. The rural mobile segment represents a huge opportunity to bank the unbanked population, thereby adding a revenue stream. In a new report, Mobile Banking in India; Dual Strategy for Rural and Urban Segments, Celent explains the mobile banking ecosystem in India and looks at the trends driving the growth in its urban and rural subsegments. The report looks at the prospects of mobile banking from both a regulatory perspective and an industry perspective. In India’s urban segment, mobile banking is an enabling fifth channel, and in the rural segment, mobile banking is a primary mode of financial inclusion. In both segments, the two fundamental factors affecting the growth of mobile banking are regulations and technology. Nontransactional s will remain the majority in India because they will continue to use online banking and other payment mechanisms. Government-to-person (G2P) payments will be the major growth driver for rural mobile banking. Regulatory changes are also a big driver. Celent believes that, by 2012, over 60 million rural s will be beneficiaries of mobile banking through business correspondence.
25
“While the urban banking market is dominated by information services, the payment transactions segment has not picked up mainly due to regulatory limitations,” says Rajesh M R, an analyst with Celent and coauthor of the report. “However, recent relaxation of payment norms by RBI has presented a huge opportunity for this segment.” “The rural mobile banking segment is a high growth area, due to the adoption of the business correspondent model and relaxed Know Your Customer norms, but financial literacy remains a big issue for retaining the rural adopters,” says Sreekrishna Sankar, Celent analyst and coauthor of the report. Marketing strategy and The Reserve Bank of India has a mandate to be closely involved in matters relating to rural credit and banking by virtue of the provisions of Section 54 of the RBI Act. The major initiative in pursuance of this mandate was taken with sponsoring of All-India Rural Credit Survey in 1951-52. This study made agency-wise estimates of rural indebtedness and observed that cooperation has failed but it must succeed. The Report of the Committee on Directions is still considered a classic on the subject, and two of the four were, incidentally, from Andhra Pradesh. This is the origin of the policy of extending formal credit through institutions while viewing local, traditional and informal agencies as usurious. In the first stage, therefore, efforts were concentrated on developing and strengthening cooperative credit structures. The Reserve Bank of India has also been making financial contributions to the cooperative institutions through evolving institutional arrangements, especially for refinancing of credit to agriculture. While enacting the State Bank of India Act in 1955, the objective was stated to be the extension of banking facilities on a large scale, more particularly, in rural and semi-urban areas. SBI, therefore, became an important instrument of extending rural credit to supplement the efforts of cooperative institutions. In 1969, 14 major commercial banks were nationalised and the objective, inter alia, was "to control the heights of economy". The nationalised banks thus became important instruments for advancement of rural banking in addition to cooperatives and State Bank of India. The next step to supplement the efforts of cooperatives and commercial banks was the establishment of Regional Rural Banks in 1975 in different states with equity participation from commercial banks, Central and State Governments. By 1982, to consolidate the various arrangements made by the RBI to promote/ supervise 26
institutions and channel credit to rural areas, NABARD was established. Though several efforts were made to increase the flow of institutional credit for agricultural and rural lending, there were mismatches in credit and production. Field studies conducted to determine the reason revealed that it was due to absence of effective local level planning. It was felt that with the establishment of large network of branches, a system could be adopted to assign specific areas to each bank branch in which it can concentrate on focussed lending and contribute to the development of the area. With a view to implementing this approach, RBI introduced a scheme of "Service Area Approach" for commercial banks. To further supplement the institutional mechanism, the concept of Local Area Banks was taken up in 1996-97 and in-principle approval has been given for 8 Local Area Banks. As regards cost of credit, for most of the period, the istered interest rate regime was applicable for bank lending and this included concessional for priority sector. Currently, all interest rates on bank advances including in rural areas are deregulated and there is no link between priority sector and interest rate, though there are some regulations on interest rates by size of advance i.e. below Rs. 2 lakh in respect of commercial banks. As regards policy measures to enhance flow of credit to rural areas, apart from availability of credit lines from the Reserve Bank of India, the concept of priority sector was evolved to ensure directed credit. Currently, the stipulation is that domestic commercial banks should extend credit to the extent of 40 per cent of the total net bank credit to priority sector as a whole, of which 18 per cent should be specifically for agriculture. Out of the target of 18 per cent for agriculture, at least 13.5 per cent should be by way of direct loans to agriculture and remaining could be in the form of indirect loans. Where a bank fails to fulfil its commitment towards priority sector lending, it is currently required to contribute to Rural Infrastructure Development Fund set up by NABARD. NABARD in turn provides these funds to State Governments and state owned corporations to enable them to complete various types of rural infrastructure projects. It is pertinent to recognise that there are a large number of credit linked programmes sponsored by the Government for direct assault on poverty. In programmes relating to self-employment and women welfare, the multiplicity of programmes has been reduced by having a comprehensive and consolidated programme named Swaranjayanti Gram Swarojgar Yojna. The financial sector reforms, which were introduced from 1991 onwards were aimed at transforming the credit institutions into organisationally strong, financially viable and operationally efficient units. The measures introduced include reduction in budgetary and concessionality of resources, preparation of Development Action Plans and g of Memoranda of 27
Understanding with the major controllers, and introduction of prudential norms relating to income recognition and asset classification for RRBs and cooperative banks. The lending rates for these institutions have also been deregulated. Other measures of liberalisation include allowing non-target group financing for RRBs, direct financing for SCBs and CCBs, and liberalisation in investment policies and non-fund business. These measures have contributed to many RRBs turning around and becoming more vibrant institutions. In the case of cooperative banks, there is greater awareness of the problems of officialisation and politicisation and initiatives in this regard include legislative actions on cooperative banks in Andhra Pradesh. Recently, several policy initiatives have been taken to advance rural banking. These includ additional capital contribution to NABARD by the RBI and the Government of India, recapitalisation and restructuring of RRBs, simplification of lending procedures as per the Gupta Committee recommendations, preparation of a special credit plans by public sector banks and launching of Kisan Credit Cards. Finally, a scheme linking self-help groups with banks has been launched under the aegis of NABARD to augment the resources of micro credit institutions. A Committee has gone into various measures for developing micro credit, and has submitted its report, which is under the consideration of the RBI. In respect of cooperatives, a Task Force under the chairmanship of my esteemed and affectionate colleague Shri Jagdish Capoor, Deputy Governor has been constituted to review the status and make recommendations for improvement. Undeniably, these initiatives have enabled a very wide network of rural financial institutions, development of banking culture, penetration of formal credit to rural areas and a counter to the dominance of moneylenders. These initiatives have also financed modernisation of rural economies and implementation of anti-poverty and self-employment programmes. However, for the purpose of focussing on the future, generalisation on some concerns regarding the current approach to rural credit and banking would be appropriate. Firstly, the cooperative banks have different layers and many of them have significantly large non-performing assets (NPAs). Many cooperatives are undercapitalised. The public sector banking system also exhibits NPAs, and some of them have so far been provided with recapitalised funds. The RRBs also exhibit NPAs and these have been recapitalised from the Government of India so far, which would imply a total recapitalisation of double the amount
28
provided by Government of India. Secondly, according to the All-India Debt and Investment Survey, 1991-92, the share of debt to institutional agencies in the case of rural households has increased marginally from 61.2 per cent to 64 per cent between 1981 and 1991. However, it must be noted that this figure relates to debt outstanding and the overall share of the institutional credit in the total debt market is likely to be smaller than what this figure indicates. Thirdly, the cost of financial intermediation by the various rural financial institutions is considered to be on the high side. The difference between the cost of resources made available to NABARD by Reserve Bank of India and the commercial rates of interest at which the cooperative banks lend for agriculture in the deregulated interest rate regime is also considered to be on the high side. Fourthly, empirical studies indicate that institutional credit is more likely to be available for well to do among the rural community. Fifthly, empirical studies also indicate that relatively backward regions have less access to institutional credit than others do. Sixthly, the non-availability of timely credit and the cumbersome procedures for obtaining credit are also attributed to the functioning of the financial institutions, though this is equally valid for rural and urban banking. Finally in regard to Government sponsored schemes, there has been overlap in ability in as much as the beneficiaries are identified on a t basis. Banks have been indicating that NPAs are proportionately more due to this overlapping. An important development in the formal segment of the rural financial markets is the growing significance of non-banking financial companies, in particular, in hire purchase and leasing operations. They also finance traders of agricultural inputs and output. The NBFCs have only recently been brought under the regulatory regime of RBI. While their importance is recognised in financing diversified rural agriculture, its extent and scope of operations has not been adequately researched. Marketing strategy and Dynamics of Rural Economy Problems, prospects and solutions to many of the issues mentioned have been researched and debated, primarily with a view to strengthening, revamping or re-orienting rural financial institutions. However, there is merit in viewing the problems of rural credit and rural banking in a wider context. In this regard, it will be useful to recognise some dynamics of rural economy. First, services sector is getting increasing importance in the rural areas also -from coffee shops to cable television operators. Assessing and meeting of credit needs of this sector is important. Second, the integration between rural and urban areas has increased 29
significantly, with the result, mobility of labour, capital, products and even credit between the two is increasing. Third, commercialisation of agriculture, particularly the increasing role of cash crops like cotton has resulted in substantial role for suppliers' and buyers' credit. Thus, fertiliser and pesticide are supplied to farmers on credit, often on deferred payment basis. In such deferred payment arrangements, credit are built into price and hence it is difficult to isolate . Similarly, the commission-agents advance money towards purchase of output from farmers, which amounts to providing credit and includes an element of forward trading. These arrangements are often entered into on a voluntary basis. The present banking system does not generally encourage financing the transactions of this nature. However, a few nonbanking financial companies do provide indirect finance for such purpose. Fourth, compared to cereal production, other food items, including poultry and fish are growing at a faster pace. In other words, rural agriculture is getting increasingly diversified in of products and processes. Fifth, in areas where commercialisation of agriculture has reached significant levels, the traditional landlord-based tenancy is replaced with commercial-based tenancy. Where intensive cultivation of cash crops such as cotton is called for, this has become quite common. However, the present credit and banking procedures do not cater to the working capital needs of such commercial based tenancy relationship. Sixth, given the diversified activities, and large work force in rural areas, there is increasing recourse to multiple occupations to earn a decent livelihood. For example, a small farmer is also a petty trader and may also be a satellite based cable television operator in the village. The end use specification and monitoring of credit is more difficult in such circumstances. Seventh, to the extent employment and indeed incomes could be seasonal, especially for agricultural labour, there is reason to seek and obtain consumption loans. Such assurance is possible with prosperity in rural employment. Present arrangements in formal credit markets are inadequate to meet such requirements. Eighth, while there is significant commercialisation and diversification of rural economies, progress is very uneven in different parts of the country. So, there are still many areas, where exploitation of tribals by money lenders or of agricultural labourers by landlord-money lenders, still persists. Norms and procedures of credit, therefore, need to be different to meet varying circumstances. Ninth, from the data on credit deposit ratios, it is clear that the banking system is a conduit for net transfer of financial savings from rural to non-rural sectors. On the other hand, a major
30
part of informal markets would be local and hence savings would be locally deployed, within the rural areas. Marketing strategy and Rural Credit Markets: New Realities As mentioned earlier in the approach to rural banking, the basic thrust of our policy has been to promote institutional credit and eliminate or ignore informal finance. However, in reality, while formal credit has expanded its share, informal finance continues to be significant. The idea of promotion of Self-Help Groups and micro financing is an indirect ission of necessity of informal finance. The future of rural banking cannot be appreciated without fully understanding both formal and informal rural credit markets, especially their linkages. Since in the earlier sections, organisation and functioning of the formal credit system in the rural areas has been explained, in this section nature of informal markets and the linkages will be explored. The informal financial market which is legal but officially unrecorded comprises unregulated financial activities i.e., outside the orbit of officially regulated financial intermediaries. In the informal financial transactions, one could treat borrowing and lending among friends and relatives as occasional and not part of such an informal market. Consequently, there are three broad
types
of
informal
financial
transactions,
viz.,
well-defined
group,
tied-
lending/borrowing; and untied lending/borrowing activities. In the literature on well-defined groups, there are three broad types namely Rotating Savings and Credit Associations (ROSCA); Accumulated Savings and Credit Associations (ASCRA) and hybrid forms of both. There are some variations under each category. Basic characteristics of these groups are that they are voluntary in nature, usually among equals, with little or no outside or interference. Often, have some special bonds based on religion, caste, status, neighbourhood, etc. In brief, there is no patronclient framework. In essence, therefore, these arrangements among well-defined groups, though important, should not in my view be included in the concept of informal financial markets. In the recent past, there have been efforts to provide a bridge between formal financial markets and these well-defined groups in the form of ‘micro-finance' initiatives. However, these initiatives do not constitute marketisation of activities of well-defined groups. Thus, the informal financial markets are those which are outside the orbit of officially regulated institutions. These informal debt transactions may involve tied debt transactions and untied debt transactions. The general approach, at least at the policy level, to informal market whether tied or untied, has not been positive since informal debt market has been historically equated with either landlord or 31
moneylender. The transactions are considered to be expensive, especially in view of what is held to be of usurious nature of interest rates. It is considered to be financing unproductive expenditures since consumption needs are financed. Sometimes, it is said that there are often unequal and exploitative arrangements, say, between the landlord and the tenant or the agricultural labourer. Finally, it is held that, since these are unregulated, they are prima facie not desirable. Yet, the fact remains that informal debt markets do prevail, and studies have shown that in some areas in our country, they for 70 to 80 per cent of debt transactions. Studies have also shown that many poor people have no access to institutional credit. The arrangements in informal debt markets are said to be flexible, and sometimes have in-built risk sharing arrangements. These credit arrangements do provide for smoothening of consumption and production requirements. Transaction costs in of certainty, timeliness, procedural requirements, number of trips, etc. are somewhat negligible although there may be hidden costs in tied lending. Moreover, while formal markets tend to cater to less risky borrowings, informal markets provide for the more risky borrowings and thus serve a purpose. Finally, it has been stated in the literature that financial repression like directed credit, high reserve ratios, interest rate ceilings, branch licensing, etc. make informal financial markets relatively attractive and popular. Perhaps, one way of reconciling the conflicting views on usefulness of informal credit is to recognise some emerging realities of both formal and informal markets. This would also help a rethink on approaches to rural credit and rural banking. First, it is no longer the case that the money lender and informal financing are always synonymous, in view of the dynamics of rural economy already described involving suppliers credit, buyers credit and credit for services sector. Second, informal markets are less significant now than before, and have to face competition or at least accept benchmarking of formal credit. The concept of monopoly of moneylender in rural areas is not true in many areas now. Third, when informal financial market is linked to socially undesirable activities, there is certainly a cause for concern though the available evidence shows that such a link is more a metropolitan or urban phenomenon rather than a rural one. Fourth, bank credit is really not severely restricted to what can be officially determined as productive, since most of the credit-card financing by the banks is, in fact, financing of consumption and at interest rates comparable to those prevailing in the rural informal debt markets. In other words, it is no longer unethical for banks to finance consumption credit
32
through the credit card route. Credit card business, so far, is an essentially urban phenomenon. Hence, the financing of consumption by informal markets in rural areas cannot be frowned upon when it is being done by banks through their credit card business. Fifth, the real extent of informal markets is grossly understated in any survey that views data on outstanding debt since the turnover of debt is ittedly much lower for public institutions than for private lending. The turnover-differential is on of several factors, including preference for short term finance and better recovery-performance in informal markets. Sixth, the social significance of informal credit is more than its proportion in financial since the poorer sections draw far larger amounts from informal than formal markets. Seventh, a significant part of informal market is through leasing, hire purchase, deferred payment, etc. with finance often provided by NBFCs. The informal market is providing a range of financial products, which the formal banking system is not able to. Eighth, studies have demonstrated that expansion of literacy and education tends to increase the access of rural folk to formal credit, reduce the informal transaction costs in dealings with formal credit institutions and improves their resistance to malpractices attributable to landlord or moneylender. The exploitative nature of informal markets is more pronounced in tribal or less developed areas while productive nature of informal markets is more pronounced in prosperous villages. Indeed, one can argue that in many areas, the formal credit structure has provided a positive institutional alternative to the moneylenders and thus marginalising his role in providing credit to rural masses. Marketing strategy and Linkages in Rural Debt Markets Having recognised that one cannot wish away informal markets, some tentative generalisations on the relative roles of formal and informal markets and on the linkages between them would also be necessary to capture the emerging but complex realities. Such generalisations are possible on the basis of empirical studies. First, the formal credit has a tendency to flow more easily to agriculturally developed regions and to relatively larger farmers leaving the backward regions and small farmers to be largely served by the informal market. This phenomenon is generally explained by four factors viz., poor-resource endowment features of the borrower, poor personal factors (education, social etc), underdevelopment of a region and higher transaction costs. Second, as per empirical studies, transaction costs associated with formal credit include fees for procuring necessary certificates (open), travel and related expenses including loss of 33
wages etc., and informal or unofficial commissions (hidden). The transaction costs vary with type of credit agency involved, the type of borrower and farm-size. Third, uncertainties and delays usually associated with formal credit can also be treated as additions to the transaction costs. Fourth, the true cost of borrowing from the formal credit system is thus higher than nominal cost if the above informal transaction costs are also included. To the extent some transaction costs are fixed, the effective cost of borrowings for smaller loans tends to be relatively higher than for a larger loan. Fifth, there are usually hidden costs or concealed interest rates in respect of informal credit also, which have to be added to the nominal costs to arrive at the true cost. These hidden costs generally relate to tied lending, tied to land, labour, input or output. The tied advance in respect of labour is particularly relevant for migratory labour. The hidden costs are usually in the form of undervaluation of labour and output of borrowers and overvaluation of inputs supplied by lender. Sixth, the choice between formal and informal credit depends on both the access and relative true costs. Thus, recourse to informal credit, ittedly at far higher nominal costs, is to be explained partly in of effective costs and the extent of supply of formal credit. Seventh, in assessing relative roles, both supply and demand side bottlenecks of formal credit need to be appreciated. The former relate to asset-based lending policies and complex formalities and procedures, while the latter relate to poor endowment, lower education and social, usually caste-based in backward regions. Viewed differently, a larger role for informal credit may arise due to low level of commercialisation and monopoly power of moneylender; and it may also arise due to high level of commercialisation of agriculture when supply from formal channel cannot match significant demand for credit. Eighth, it is also necessary to recognise that, to the extent informal markets tend to lend to borrowers who are relatively less creditworthy, risk- is bound to be higher. This would also get reflected in higher nominal interest rates in informal markets and indeed higher true cost, though it may not be so high if it is net of risk . It is clear that the critical issue in respect of informal credit is the manner in which the linkages among the participants in the market operate and result in varying degrees of hidden costs. It is possible to make some exploratory postulates here. First, trader-lenders are likely to provide most of production - credit, while farmer-lender or moneylender is likely to provide most of consumption - credit. It is, of course, possible that some individuals combine the functions of farmer, trader and moneylender. Second, informal markets are unlikely to 34
finance credit for investment purposes, given the time preference. Third, the levels of education are likely to reduce the scope for gross overvaluation or undervaluation in linkedtransactions. Fourth, the inter-linked transactions among parties with equal bargaining power are likely to minimise the hidden costs. Fifth, from the supply side, farmer-lenders may tend to be associated with land and labour market linkages while trader-lender is likely to be associated with input-output markets. On the demand side, agricultural labour may be associated with land and labour markets while the farmer-cultivator with input-output linkages. In the process, it is likely that a farmer would be a borrower from a trader and a lender to agricultural labour, a common phenomenon in villages. It will, therefore, be over simplification to divide the rural population into lenders and borrowers or exploiters and exploited. Sixth, similarly it is necessary to appreciate the role of linkages in credit-riskmitigation. In fact, the risk reducing element of linkages are not built into formal creditchannels. Incidentally to the extent the transaction costs are front loaded in respect of formal credit, there is no incentive to repay while the true costs of informal credit are spread out. Seventh, in of bargaining power among the class of borrowers, the agricultural labour and migratory labour appear to be weakest except in agriculturally prosperous areas where labour-shortage is acute to cater to agricultural and other operations. Similarly, the differential in bargaining power between large and small borrowers is similar to that between large corporate and small-industrialists in urban areas. In brief, the linkages between formal and informal markets are complex, contextual and dynamic. The two markets appear to compete with and also supplement each other. Technology and marketing strategy We should recognise that the role of banks, which is central to formal credit in rural areas, is fast changing. Many non-banks are providing avenues for savers and funds for investment purposes. Banks themselves are undertaking non-traditional activities. Banks are also becoming what are called universal banks and are already providing a range of financial services such as investments, merchant banking and even insurance products. Similarly, non banks are also undertaking bank like activities. At present in India, these are mostly confined to urban areas, but they will sooner than later spread to rural areas. Another development relates to the gradual undermining of the importance of branches of banks. The emergence of new technology allows access to banking and banking services without physical direct recourse to the bank premise by the customer. The concept of 35
Automated Teller Machines (ATMs) is the best example. At present, ATMs are city oriented in our country. It is inevitable that ATMs will be widely used, in semi-urban and rural areas. The technology-led process is leading us to what has been described as virtual banking. The benefits of such virtual banking services are manifold. Firstly, it confers the advantage of lower cost of handling a transaction. Secondly, the increased speed of response to customer requirements under virtual banking vis-à-vis branch banking can enhance customer satisfaction. Thirdly, the lower cost of operating branch network along with reduced staff costs leads to cost efficiency. Fourthly, it allows the possibility of improved quality and an enlarged range of services being available to the customer more rapidly and accurately at his convenience. It may not be possible to deny these facilities to rural areas in our country since, if banks do not provide them, some non-banks will do it. Another development relates to the increasing popularity of credit cards, which are bound to reach rural areas. Many Public Sector Banks are already in credit card business. In fact, multipurpose cards could be a facility that IT could usher in for rural population. The potential can be illustrated with SMART cards. SMART cards – which are basically cards using computer circuits in them thereby making them ‘intelligent' – would serve as multipurpose cards. SMART cards are essentially a technologically improved version of credit and debit cards and could be used also as ATM cards. They could be used for credit facilities at different locations by the holders. SMART cards could also be used for personal identification and incidentally for monitoring credit usage. For the spread of virtual-banking and SMART cards to rural areas, it is essential that electric power and telecom connectivity are continuous and supplies do not drop especially during the hours when a bank's transactional activity is at relatively high levels. The banks could, under such assured supply conditions acquire the required banking software and also put in place the necessary networking for providing anywhere banking facilities in rural and semi-urban areas also. Like banks in other parts of the world, Indian banks will have to get interested in providing diversified range of financial products and services along with those that they are already providing, by using technological advances. As the level of education in rural areas rises and affluence spreads, customers will start seeking efficient, quicker and low cost services. As the financial system diversifies and other types of financial intermediaries become active, in rural areas, savers would turn towards mutual funds or the savers themselves decide to deploy part of their financial surpluses into equities and debentures as also other fixed income securities. 36
The bulk of bank deposits in the rural areas are currently longer term deposits and as these come down, there would be a distinct shortening of the average maturity structure of bank deposits with an increase in asset liability mismatches. The spreads that the banks now enjoy will progressively shrink making it more difficult for them to survive. As more and more intermediaries enter rural areas with greater level of technology, traditional banking business will come under pressure. In order to face the competitive pressures being exerted by the recently set up market savvy banks, banks which have extensive branch network in most of the existing and potential rich rural and semi-urban areas may have to provide such services. Issues It is clear that significant progress has been made, since independence, in expanding bank branches and banking habits in the rural areas, through a variety of institutional innovations. An impressive segment of rural economy has been brought into the ambit of formal financial intermediation, mainly through the public sector banking system, and to some extent, through cooperatives and RRBs. The future of banking in rural areas would, however, depend on several factors that have been described, namely, how the current concerns are addressed taking into the dynamics of transformation in rural economies, the new realities in credit markets, the linkages between formal and informal markets, and the impact of financial as well as technological progress on the systems of financial intermediation. Consequently, public policy will have to address several issues to ensure a sound and efficient banking system in the service of rural areas. The more important of such issues relate to the approach, institutions, supply, cost, and related policies Marketing strategy and Approach In the past, the major instruments of public policy were cooperatives and public-sector banking system. However, with the diversification of ownership of public sector banks and the overall thrust of financial-sector reform, a review of institutional arrangements, mainly in the incentive framework for credit-delivery appears necessary. Similarly, in the area of cooperatives also, a reduced role for Government including in providing refinance is being advocated. This desirable approach would also need a review of institutional arrangements, in particular in delayering and debureaucratising the cooperatives. Further, there are new institutions and new forms of financial intermediation that are emerging – be it mutual funds or more important for rural areas, non-banking financial 37
companies. Any approach to rural-development should consider capturing, at least the activities of non-banking financial companies as part of formal rural financial markets. Moreover, in many parts of the country, growth of literacy and diversification of the economy have brought about new characteristics and linkages between formal and informal financial markets in rural areas. The latter does play a significant part in rural economy. Hence, the two markets should be treated as competing and co-existing, and in fact the policy should seek to utilise informal markets also for public interest. A small beginning has been made in this direction, through initiatives on micro finance. A policy of analysing and monitoring of rural financial markets as a whole is critical for the future and devoting attention only to banks and cooperatives may not suffice. I would hasten to add that a policy-focus on informal markets does not at all imply extending regulation to informal markets. In fact, the Report of Task Force on micro-finance of NABARD (1999) has recommended extending regulatory framework for micro-finance institutions, and in my view this recommendation is fraught with difficulties. Funding by banks and regulated NBFCs of micro-finance institutions should be encouraged and guidelines provided, but regulation of micro-finance institutions may not be prima facie wise. In any case, research and micro studies encoming both formal and informal segments would help the policy makers appreciate relative roles and linkages in rural financial markets as a whole. In other words, policy analysis should perhaps consider expanding its attention from rural banking to rural financial markets. Enhancing effective supply of credit in such rural financial markets would be a logical objective of policy, thus enlarging the current attention to include both directly disbursed credit by the banking or cooperative sectors and indirect supply. Similarly, reducing the true cost of credit availability to rural areas would be yet another objective, expanding the attention of policy to include both nominal cost of credit from banking or cooperative sector and true cost in formal and informal markets. In an increasingly deregulated environment, this objective would imply attention to competitive efficiency involving proceduralsimplification also, in respect of banks and cooperatives.
Finally, the approach may expand from delivery of credit to rural areas to making available financial services and products to savers, investors and consumers in the rural areas. In other words, it should be recognised that rural financial markets comprise both depositors or savers 38
and borrowers or investors. Institutions Among the institutions involved in rural credit, cooperatives have a special place in the RBI. There is full appreciation of the problems and efforts are underway to workout a package for revival and may be, rebirth of rural cooperative banks by a Committee headed by Deputy Governor Shri Jagdish Capoor. The Committee would naturally address issues relating to legal framework, and incurring costs of addressing problems related to overhang of the past. In addition, the Committee, I trust, would consider desirability of cooperative banks' foray into non-fund-based activities, such as fee-based financial services on behalf of mutual funds or insurance-products. The cooperatives could, in fact help, retail Treasury Bills and Government Securities in rural areas. Diversified financial products will be increasingly demanded and supplied in the rural areas, and co-operatives should not be left out of this trend of providing multiple-products through a single window. This would also imply, going beyond the somewhat closed loop of preferred financial relations within cooperative system into a multiple s between cooperative banks and other financial intermediaries, largely utilising technological improvement. Commercial banks are being reformed in accordance with recommendations of the Narasimham Committee. The RRBs are being recapitalised. These efforts in regard to banks would presumably recognise the trends in providing financial services to enable them to exercise necessary flexibility and dynamism that is warranted by fast changing world. Similarly, the future role of NABARD could be addressed because the organisational setup, funding and activities will have to reflect the basic logic of financial sector reform viz. changing roles of owner, regulator, refinancing, subsidised credit, government-funding and cooperatives. Enhancing Effective Supply Some analysts argue that supply-led strategy in regard to rural credit has not been successful, since institutional spread and directed-lending have not had the desired impact. While accepting that demand has to play its role, and real-demand also implies negotiating strength of the borrower in respect of financial institutions, it will be inappropriate to conclude that supply should necessarily follow demand. Mere presence of rural credit institutions, does not 39
amount to availability of supply. Similarly, mere prescriptions of priority lending would not ensure supply. For example, prescription of priority-sector lending relates to percentage of credit outstanding rather than advances. Further, there is no reward for overshooting the target and undershooting is not really penalised since amounts of shortfall need to be placed in a fund istered by NABARD with a totally risk-free return of 11.5 percent for a five-year advance. These funds are actually lent to State Governments, thus to an extent replacing rural credit to agriculture with credit to State Government for rural development. While as a transient measure during a period conspicuous for incomplete projects, such an arrangement was justifiable, this should not become a permanent feature as it would have obviously perverse effects. The coverage of definition of priority sector also leads to some difference between apparent supply and effective supply. Thus, the base for calculating priority sector excludes commercial banks' investments, which are expanding rapidly. The procedural bottlenecks resulting in delayed supply also, in some ways, amount to erosion of effective supply. At the same time, there may be some effective supplies which are not reckoned for supply under priority-sector. There may be funds channelled by banks to rural area through urbanbranches or through other intermediaries such as NBFCs. There is perhaps a case for some research and studies on policy of directed lending so that we could improve on the incentive and policy framework to enhance effective supply. For example, the definition and coverage of priority sector for agriculture could be revisited and lending to agriculture by banks through NBFC's could be considered for inclusion in prioritysector, as has been done to ensure flow of credit to truck operators. Yet another area in effective supply relates to lending by banks under government sponsored programmes, which has significant non-commercial considerations. Several issues relating to both supply and ability arise due to involvement of both Government and banks. A more transparent approach, for example, by separately ing for them as policy-induced lending would help isolate and monitor this supply, apart from isolating the non-performing assets on this in the balance sheets of banks. An important bottleneck in the delivery of credit has been the negligible use of billdiscounting for services sector. Current policies and procedures restrict this instrument to goods. It has been decided by the RBI to constitute a Committee to explore ways by which bank finance can be made available to service sector. The Committee, with representation from public, private sector and foreign banks also is expected to study international 40
experience, our policies and procedures and make recommendations in two months. This important step recognises that about half of our Gross Domestic Product is in services sector and would also help flow of bank finance to the growing services sector in rural areas. Reducing True Cost The major reasons for the true cost of credit from rural financial institutions being higher than nominal costs are mainly scarcity of supply and transaction costs. Enhancing effective supply would be an important strategy of reducing the true cost. Encouraging competition would be yet another strategy. A review of procedural requirements, such as eliminating mandatory forms and replacing them with locally determined procedures, could also be considered. All non-verified documentation could, for instance, be replaced with self-declaration by the borrower. Repeated visits and consequent transaction costs can be avoided by several procedural simplifications - going beyond Gupta Committee recommendation. In particular, growth of information technology and its application in banking would warrant a thorough review of products, procedures and linkages among rural financial institutions. Arbitrage in financial markets is inevitable and prevalence of such operations cannot be ignored. Arbitrage between formal and informal markets and between production loans and consumption needs is also common. Thus, keeping the true cost artificially low in formal markets, the rural financial institutions would encourage arbitrage and erode the clear potential for profit. Indeed, an appropriate strategy may be to reduce the difference between nominal and true cost and ensure that true cost reflects market conditions, including for credit risk. As already mentioned, provision of diverse financial products and services in the rural areas would enhance income to banks and help reduce the ittedly large spreads in interest rates. Thus, among the efforts to reduce nominal and true costs of credit in rural areas would be provision of multiplicity of financial services by rural financial institutions, taking advantage of developments in technology and financial markets. Related Policies There is increasing recognition that, the spread of literacy and generation of growth impulses in the rural sector would be very significant factors in enhancing effective supply and reducing true cost of rural credit. More specifically, the desired spread of technology and 41
trickledown of urban financial products to rural areas would require concerted action in four areas. First and foremost, insurance, especially of crops, should penetrate the rural areas to mitigate the risks to both farmer and lender. The lack of penetration of insurance is perhaps an important reason for lenders seeking tied and other risk-mitigation arrangements through informal markets. Second, there should be assured supply of electric power so that functioning of systems is not disrupted. Third, telecommunication network needs to be dependable and financial sector needs to ensure a network. We, in the RBI, have already launched INFINET. Fourth, the institutional and regulatory framework should enable rural financial institutions to operate in diverse financial products and services. We, in the RBI are currently engaged in a number of initiatives and studies. We hope to continue the process, and focus on rural credit, as mandated by the RBI Act. We would seek advice and guidance in this endeavour.
AN ICT STRUCTURE FOR RURAL BANKING ENABLEMENT 42
An ICT Structure for Rural Banking Enablement We have developed an ICT based Solution in which the banking services delivery can be done using the electronic platform. The three key principles used in this model are:a) unbundling and outsourcing non-statutory services needed for banking and establishing digital rural information infrastructure. b) automating the workflow, the records management and follow-up and recover c) the use of entrepreneurship model for achieving effectiveness, efficiency and economy in the performance of the rural information infrastructure, rural information services and other follow-up functions e.g., credit rating of rural individuals and analytics for decision .
“GANASEVA “RURAL SERVICES DELIVERY MODEL – ELECTRONIC DELIVERY VERSUS PAYMENT (DVP) PLATFORM “Ganaseva” (Gana=People; Seva=Service) uses technology for bridging “service divide” by empowering rural individuals and by establishing digital information infrastructure and electronic platform for rural commerce and development.
THE “GANASEVA” is an integrated ICT-based solution for delivery of financial and non-financial services for improving the provision of quality services to all the rural people by increasing the effective access, by creating rural information infrastructure and by providing an electronic platform for transmission of information from the people to the service providers like banks. Its hall marks are empowerment of the rural individuals, integrated approach to rural commerce and financial viability through entrepreneurship and choice availability both to the people and the service providers like banks.
43
Its components are Digital Rural Information Infrastructure, Customer Data Integration and Credit rating, a shared electronic platform for various services, Provision of technology to banking services including ATM Services. Benefits include financial inclusion of rural population, providing the banking services in a pro-active manner, enabling the banks to offer highly individualized bundle of services, and reduction of costs through shared infrastructure for data collection and updation and shared mobile service-delivery mechanism and generally enabling the innovation and spread of banking and other services by providing an efficient electronic platform and promote commerce and development. The solution proposes common infrastructure for the rural data collection and information management and processing and the sharing of the delivery channel by the banks with a view to substantially reducing the transaction costs and improving the speed and quality of delivery. The elements involved in the solution are the establishment of a data center and ensuring its two way connectivity to the mobile multiservice delivery system available at the villages for providing the banking, extension and other services as well as connectivity to all the concerned banks and other service-providing agencies. The solution involves the outsourcing of the data management as well as of the delivery channel establishment and operations with required safeguards regarding the data ownership and operations. The model envisaged provides a cost-effective but efficient technology platform for rural banking. Technologically, the solution involves four main elements: ESTABLISHMENT OF DIGITAL RURAL INFORMATION INFRASTRUCTURE MULTI SERVICE DELIVERY SYSTEM (MSDS) INTEGRATED MULTI-ENTITY DATABASE SYSTEM (IMDS) SERVICE PROVIDER’S WORKSTATION
The special Features of the Model are the following: • Comprehensiveness of the solutions covering both front-end and back-end 44
operations involving the delivery of credit and other services. • Proactive provision of services to the people • Provision for exploiting the existing sources and interfacing with available data services and other e-governance solution- providers. • Expert systems for processing of credit and other services • Easy and secure interface for the rural people with biometric security measures • Assisted credit delivery with provision for clarification from the banks etc., through the voice & video • Provision of the information required for credit approvals
• Provision of a data base tool for capturing of the rural data and the technical specifications of such rural data base and its architecture
Figure 1 below gives a diagrammatic representation of the Model.
Figure 1 DIAGRAMMATIC REPRESENTATION OF THE MODEL
45
46
GANASEVA Model for Rural Banking: Implementation Experience The project was implemented in five villages in the Honavar block of the Uttara Kannada district of Karnataka, India having approximately 4000 families, involved in essentially agricultural activity. The banks which participated in this project are State bank of India, Syndicate Bank, who had agreed to use the data / documents available through the system. Besides the rural information service and credit rating, there is in the system for the crop loan and Kisan Credit Card and Savings Bank Operations. The Project also wanted to link the Primary Agricultural Co-operative Societies (PACS) to the system for providing banking services through their automation. The project was expected to demonstrate the feasibility of the model on the ground.
Methodology Information System We developed a model for rural information infrastructure. A reputed market research agency was employed for collection of
data and documents in proof thereof in respect of adults in all the households of the five selected villages viz., Idagunji, Apsarakonda, Kelaginoor, Malkod and Manki located in the backward Honavar block of Uttara Kannada District in Karnataka. The data collected was validated by a control set of 500 cases collected by the project coordinator and further by the of the Project Monitoring Group. Pre-programmed PDAs were used for collection of data/information, the documentary evidence and ing of this data into Server. The information was collected as per the requirement developed in consultation with the banks for providing banking services and the authentication requirements.
PDA Software
Since PDAs were used for collection of data, documents and voice, there was a need to develop a solution for that. This was done by the Envision 47
Company and the software was integrated with the RCDS System at the backend to facilitate seamless data transmission from the PDAs to the RCDS Server using web services.
Rural Credit Delivery System The functional specifications for the banking services to be provided were worked out in consultation with the bankers at the project area as well as their controlling authorities. Based on these specifications, the System Requirement Specification was worked out to develop the software. The delivered system has been installed in various locations for testing like the SBI, Honavar and PACS Kelaginoor.
Credit Rating Solution A credit rating solution for the rural individuals was prepared using a separate model developed for the purpose. Likewise, a voice-based authentication system was also developed for testing.
PACS Bank Software In order to enable the rural co-operatives to link to the RCDS system, the PACS in the area were computerized after a thorough study of their business processes and developing separate software for the purpose. This work was done by the Nelito in consultation with the Project Director, the banks and other authorities.
Document Management Software The document management software which was integrated with the RCDS system was provided by the software company Stex.
ATM Feasibility The technological feasibility of deploying the ATMs in the Project villages was tested and was found to be adequate.
Project Location, Coverage and Implementation 48
For testing and demonstrating the implementability of the above solution with respect to essentials, we undertook, and completed, a pilot project during October 2004 and January 2006 with funding from Microsoft and technology from a Microsoft-HP led coalition of ISVs. The Government and the local NGOs also actively participated. Banks like State Bank of India, Honavar and Primary Agricultural Co-operative Credit Societies have started using the systems. The project objectives were -> Establishing ICT-based Rural Information Infrastructure for providing banking services on a shared basis -> Managing and processing this data and for making it available to the various banks for acquiring customers both on the liability and assets sides. -> Shared delivery system through mobile ATMs for increasing access to rural people. The project area comprised select interior villages chosen on the basis on connectivity, contiguity and proximity in the backward Honavar block in Karnataka. Participating banks and financial institutions in the project were the State Bank of India, Syndicate Bank, and the Primary Agricultural Co-operative Credit Societies at Kelaginoor, Balkoor and Manki. The coverage included all adult individual in the villages and was not limited to any target group like micro finance or self-help-groups.
Benefits to Banks, People and to the System The benefits to the banks from the model are the availability of mechanism for achieving and expanding effective access to the rural areas in a non-traditional economical way, identifying the potential customers and providing highly individualized banking experience in proactive manner including individualized risk assessment; availability of reliable information infrastructure in digital form with a mechanism to update on a continuous basis; facility to do offsite identification of the prospects online; credit rating to enable building of quality portfolio and facility for building portfolio according to the ALM requirements of the banks. The benefits to the rural people are banking. The benefits to the economic system include availability electronic platform for services delivery, digital rural information infrastructure enabling the development of nationwide date grid; authentic inputs for grassroots level planning and Government’s socioeconomic interventions; ready availability of the information for the markets and market participants to penetrate rural area and provision for enabling different methods of service 49
delivery like kiosks. ATMs for pursuing cost-efficiency through extensive outsourcing and lean processes to suit the local realities.
Findings from the Project Implementation Major findings from the Project implementation are the following: a. Building rural information infrastructure is possible using technology, in the rural areas. b. The service providers have uniformly expressed the need for such an information system. c. There is a need and scope for developing and making available rural credit rating. d. The computerization of the PACS is useful to improve the quality of working of the PACS, besides having potential for improving governance through linkage to the Credit delivery system. e. ATM-based mobile service delivery systems are deployable in rural areas using the CDMA technology
ICT Framework for delivery of rural services The need and potential for the application of Ganaseva Model Framework with regional and functional variations of processes and the delivery channels in India and even beyond appear to be substantial. Since the information and banking are direct services as well as infrastructural services, the Model can be expanded for providing various other services.
Rural Services Delivery Framework As the raison d’ etre of the Indian Rural Information Infrastructure (RII) is to enable the provision of rural services of high quality at low costs in a sustainable manner in a self financing framework, it has to be derived from model for delivery of rural services. In our framework of such rural services, the banking services occupy the preeminent position. Given the scenario of poverty and economic deprivation and the need for accelerating capital formation in rural areas for promoting growth and income in villages, the gamut of rural activities need to have the economic transactions at the centre. This focus is relevant because the existing delivery systems have been found to be wanting, for whatever systemic reasons, in making credit and banking services available in adequate measures in the rural areas in India Therefore, any rural services strategy will have banking 50
services delivery as a core function. The utility service provision which partly use banking as the payment system infrastructure could be the second layer. The delivery of the rest of the services like governance, information, education, health, extension and occasional requirements like investment, trade and documentation might form the third dimension.
Digital Rural Information Infrastructure The emphasis on data quality and reconciliation processing, coverage of various subject areas – patient data identification for health care, customer identification for e-commerce, beneficiary identification for the poverty alleviation programs / Employment guarantee schemes of the state, removal of the barriers for providing financial services to the poor, the swamping of conflicting / segmented information , the need to anticipate the need of s for sentient computing- have all accentuated the need for establishing a robust rural information infrastructure, for the provision of authenticated authentic information about the rural people using the ICT tools for increasing the speed, and usability and cost effectiveness. The rapid growth of technology and communication infrastructure with ubiquitous footprints is a great enabler of the rural information infrastructure (RII).The telecommunications and technology penetration of the rural areas is no longer the problem in the current Indian context of its exponential growth in availability, reach and affordability. The Rural Information Infrastructure in this context ought to put emphasis on enabling of the reaching of services to the rural people rather than taking technology to their doorsteps. The objectives of this effort could be identical with the mission of the National Information Infrastructure (NII) in the United States which is “to deliver to all Americans the information they need when they want it and where they want it at an affordable price. The Rural Information Infrastructure (RII) that is the part of the NII will reach into America’s rural areas, providing access to a broad range of information and information services.” Despite this assertion, the focus of the RII in the US was on the technology. In our model, the focus is on identifying and capturing of information content, modelling it and presenting the data in a proactive manner to the provision of various services to the rural people.
51
Our RII model involves the use of ICT for building and operating this information infrastructure involving collection, storage updation, consolidation and processing of the data and making customized offering; Entrepreneurial model with provision for assurance review by public authorities or s or both; Pay- for- use business model. The technology model involves the use of personal digital assistants (PDAs) with specially made applications for data (Voice, Picture and Data) capture, verification and validation and updating; Data Center with storage, processing and management; Delivery Nodes at the -ends and Three-way connectivity between the PDA, Data Center and Delivery Node. We have developed customized information offerings to banks and financing agencies for exemplifying our model and exploring the usefulness and implement ability of our RII model for enabling the customer acquisitions and follow-up by the banks, both on the liability and asset sides. It may be pointed out that the need for automated digitized rural information infrastructural is needed for rural financing, not only in India but in other parts of the world as well. According to The Economist Microfinance Survey “The cost of micro-finance will have to come down. At present, it is far too manpower intensive…Credit evaluation relies on character or cash flow valuation rather than the statistical techniques…… it will not be sustainable……. More competition will help reduce costs, but the biggest hope comes from new technology” and further, “In the past, the two main obstacles to providing Financial services to poor people have been lack of information and costs…. Ultimately lower costs and better information are good not just for the poor, but for everyone.”
52
Digital Rural Information Infrastructure Model Collection of data about people, including rural people, for governance and commercial purposes is a well-established activity the world over, including in India. However, in the Indian context, the collection and validation of the data about the Indian people on a comprehensive basis; the processing, analysis and presentation of this data in a friendly manner in electronic form are yet to be done. Currently, this has assumed urgency for the following reasons: (i) Achieving greater comprehensiveness about the data to meet the increasing variety of requirements at a single point (ii) Formulating delivery goals for various functionalities (iii) Need for a different implementation framework rather than the application of standard data warehousing methodology (iv) The complexity of the need. The proposed RII solution involves the use of information and Communication Technology for building and operating robust reliable authentic comprehensive digital information infrastructure involving the sourcing of the data to the maximum extent possible, together with ing documentary and non-documentary evidence, the images of the assets and the personal identification features like pictures and voice clips ; the online storage of such information in a data center directly and the classification and consolidation and processing of the data and making customized offerings to various s after appropriate value addition through analytics. We also propose an entrepreneur-based model for implementing the solution in a large country like India with a view to creating the economic incentive for the completion of this large scale multidimensional rural census with provision for the assurance review of this information infrastructure by public authorities or s or both, depending upon the purposes for which such information has to be used and also for preventing any abuse of this data for anti-social purposes. Another key feature of the model is that the s will have to pay for accessing the information needed according to the specific offerings required in order to make this model self-financing and financially viable.
53
As a specific instance of the application, the RII information services together with credit rating of the rural individuals to the banks and financing agencies has been worked out. The RII information in digital form will be stored and processed in the backend system at the data center for affording to the banking functionalities of the Rural Credit Delivery System. The banking services ed by the RII are the registration of the customer, credit rating and the opening of the bank s and provision of loans for agricultural operations. The information stored in the server is classified and grouped and made available to the banks and the customers to perform their activities in a context sensitive way. The RII data will be used for deriving a credit rating and making it available to the people and the banks. The digital RII facilitates the following in the banks: • Access to self- validated data / information with documentary proof in the digital form to the service- providers at low costs. • Providing techniques and tools for evaluation of the credit on an individual basis rather than in a standardized manner. • Applying of the information and communication technologies appropriately for reducing costs, delays, increasing accuracy, objectivity and reducing governance problems in the credit assessment. • Enabling more efficient capital allocation and improvements in quality of lending.
54
Figure 2. Rural Credit Delivery Solution using Digital Rural Information Infrastructure
55
Rural Information Infrastructure-Technology Solution The technology solution involves the use of PDA’s or Laptops with specially made applications for capturing data [voice, picture and data] with provision for clarification and validation and updating. It also envisages a data center wherein all these collected data are stored, processed and managed with suitable control procedure and provision for the audit by the s and / or public authorities. The third element is CDMA connectivity between the s of the data and the data center. There is provision for separation of the ’s transactional data from the general information infrastructure in order to make the data center viable and also enable the provision of information services on an application service provider model by keeping such operations distinctly separate from the management of the rural information infrastructure. The fourth element of the model is hubbing all these data centers in order to create an information grid for the country as a whole, in due course.
Record of progress of rural banking Policies of the current phase of financial liberalization have had an immediate, direct, and dramatic effect on rural credit. There has been a contraction in rural banking in general and in priority sector lending and preferential lending to the poor in particular (Ramachandran and Swaminathan, 2002, Shetty 2004, Chavan 2004). Let us consider a few indicators. Appendix Table 1 documents the growth of bank offices, deposits and gross bank credit in rural areas as well as the share of rural areas in the all India total from December 1969 to March 2002, for all scheduled commercial banks. The impact of bank nationalization on the growth of scheduled commercial banks in rural areas is clear: the share of rural bank offices in total bank offices jumped from 17.6 per cent in 1969 to 36 per cent in 1972. The share then rose steadily, and attained a peak of 58.2 per cent in March 1990. From then onwards, there was a gradual decline in the share of rural bank offices, and the share fell below 50 per cent in 1998 and thereafter. In fact, there was an absolute contraction in the number of bank offices in the 1990s: 2,723 rural bank offices were closed between March 1994 and March 2000.
56
Official banking statistics do not, unfortunately, give us information on the volume of advances in a specific year. The basic source of data on banking is the Reserve Bank of India’s annual Banking Statistics. Data in this document are provided on “credit outstanding,” which is the total amount advanced, including all outstanding loans and non-performing assets, on March 31 of the reference year. Data under the head “credit sanctioned” do not represent the volume of advanced in a single year either; in fact, at the allIndia level, the figures for “credit outstanding,” “credit sanctioned,” and “credit utilised” are equal. The consequence of this method of collection and presentation of data is that there are no data at all on loan advances by banks each year, that is, on the flow of credit The data on the stock of credit show a marked deceleration in credit provision to the countryside since 1991; had we data on the actual amount disbursed each year, we would have had a clearer picture of the collapse in rural banking in the period of liberalization. The period after nationalization was characterized by an expansion of bank credit to rural areas: the credit outstanding from rural branches tripled in the 1970s, and continued to rise in the 1980s. After 1988, however, the credit outstanding from rural branches as a proportion of total credit outstanding declined, from around 15 per cent in 1987 and 1988 to 11 per cent in March 1999, and 10.2 per cent in March 2002. Turning to deposit mobilisation, rural deposits grew rapidly after nationalization; their share of aggregate deposits doubled in the 1970s, from 6.5 per cent in 1972 to 12.6 per cent in 1980 and continued to grow, although at a slower pace, in the 1980s. Once again, the peak was reached in 1990-91, when rural deposits ed for 15.5 per cent of aggregate deposits. The pace of deposit mobilization in rural areas fell in the 1990s. Given the pattern of growth of aggregate deposits and gross bank credit, it is no surprise that the credit-deposit ratio in rural areas rose after 1969. The ratio peaked at 68.6 per cent in 1984 and remained above 60 per cent until 1991. In the 1990s, the credit-deposit ratio fell sharply. One of the objectives of banking policy after nationalization was to expand the flow of credit to agriculture and small industries, or what were termed “priority sectors.” As Appendix Table 2 shows, the share of priority sectors in the total credit outstanding of scheduled commercial banks rose from 14 per cent in 1969 to 21 per cent in 1972 and then went up to 33 per cent in 1980. The RBI set a target of 40 per cent for priority sector lending and by the mid-1980s this target was met. From 1985 to 1990, 57
in fact, the target was over-achieved, that is, more than 40 per cent of total credit outstanding went to priority sectors. From 1991 to 1996, the share of priority sector credit fell, in line with the recommendations of the Narasimham Committee. At first glance, the direction in priority sector lending appears to have been reversed over the last five years. This is, however, a reversal by redefinition: “priority sector” lending now includes advances to newly-created infrastructure funds, to non-banking finance companies for on-lending to very small units, and to the food processing industry. Loans to multinationals like Pepsi, Kelloggs, Hindustan Lever and ConAgra now count as priority sector advances. More recently, loans to cold storage units, irrespective of location, have been included in the priority sector. Chandrasekhar and Ray (2004) point to the growing presence of foreign banks in India, their direct presence and their indirect presence through the purchase of shares in existing private banks. This expansion is not good news for the priority sector. When data for scheduled commercial banks are disaggregated by type of bank (public sector banks, regional rural banks, private banks and foreign banks), we find that foreign banks did not lend to rural areas or agriculture.
Pallavi Chavan (2004) has examined the growth and regional distribution of rural banking over the period 1975-2002. Chavan’s paper documents the gains made by the historically underprivileged regions of east, north-east, and central India during the period of social and development banking. These gains were reversed in the 1990s: cutbacks in rural bank branches and in rural credit-deposit ratios were steepest in the eastern and north-eastern states of India. Policies of financial liberalization have unmistakably worsened regional inequalities in rural banking in India. As already mentioned, one of our central concerns is the “credit starvation” (the term is S. L. Shetty’s) of the rural economy, which resulted in shortages of credit for all purposes, including for productive investment in agricultural and non-agricultural activity. If we examine the term loans issued by scheduled commercial banks to agriculture between 1980-81 and 1997-98 (Ramachandran and Swaminathan, 2002, Table 3), then we observe that, in real , credit outstanding rose from 1983-84 to 1990-91, but fell in the first four years after 1991 (although there was some recovery from 1995-96 onwards). It is instructive here to look at the distribution of total agricultural advances to cultivators by size classes of land holdings. The smallest cultivators i.e., those with land 58
holdings of less than 2.5 acres or marginal cultivators, were the worst affected by the post1991 decline in credit to agriculture. Agricultural credit outstanding to marginal cultivators ed for 30 per cent of total agricultural credit outstanding from commercial banks in 1990-91; its share fell to 23.8 per cent in 1999-2000 (Chavan, 2004, Table 10). At the same time, the share of credit outstanding to “small cultivators” (with between 2.5 and 5 acres) stagnated while that to large cultivators rose. Another indicator of the decline in credit to relatively poor rural households is the fact that the number of ‘small borrowal s’ (or s with a credit limit of Rs 25,000) fell in the 1990s (Chandrasekhar and Ray, 2004) The IRDP was a major component of the credit-led poverty alleviation strategy of the 1980s. The number of families assisted annually with IRDP loans rose from 2.7 million in 1980-81 to 4 million in 1984 and 4.2 million in 1987 (Ramachandran and Swaminathan 2002). Although the programme slackened after that, the number of beneficiaries in 1990-91 remained above the level of the early 1980s. After 1991, there was a steep decline in the number of IRDP beneficiaries: only 1.3 million families were assisted in 1998. If we index the number of families assisted in 1982 at 100, the number assisted in 1998 was a mere 37. The term credit disbursed by banks under IRDP followed a similar trajectory. With 1982 indexed at 100, total term credit mobilized for IRDP peaked at 113 in 1987 and went down to 52 in 1998.
VILLAGE STUDIES Case studies based on primary data help identify the impact of changes in financial policy and banking structure on patterns of indebtedness among rural households. We shall attempt to review the major results from five papers, each reporting the findings of detailed village surveys on rural credit in the contemporary period. The studies cover Baghra and Udaipur villages of Giridih district in Jharkhand, Panahar and Muidara villages of Bankura district in West Bengal, Morazha village of Kannur district in Kerala, Gokilapuram of Theni district in Tamil Nadu and Dhamar of Rohtak district and Birdhana of Fatehabad district in Haryana.
59
Gokilapuram village in south-west Tamil Nadu is a highly-irrigated, agriculturally-advanced and commercialised village. The high development of productive forces is combined with a very unequal distribution of resources: a large proportion of households are landless while a small minority control the major share of land and other assets. The availability of data from two census-type surveys of Gokilapuram, the first in 1977 and the second in 1999, with smaller surveys in the interim, particularly in 1985, allows for a discussion of changes over a relatively long period of time (Ramachandran and Swaminathan, 2004b). Resurvey data are also available for the two villages in West Bengal. Vikas Rawal first studied the villages of Panahar and Muidara in 1995-96 and restudied them in 2002 (Rawal, 2004). After land reform in the 1970s and 1980s, there were major changes in these two villages. Irrigated area, agricultural output and yields surged. As in other parts of West Bengal, agrarian structure in Panahar and Muidara is dominated by smallholders. In neighbouring Jharkhand, Surjit and Ramachandran conducted surveys of rural credit in the villages of Baghra and Udaipur in 2003. These villages are not only less developed in of agricultural production than Panahar and Muidara but also poorer in of general infrastructure and resources. Udaipur village, a village whose population was almost entirely Adivasi (or Scheduled Tribe), had fewer landless households and less inequality in the distribution of land than Baghra, a multi-caste village. Rawal and Mukherjee (2004) present some features of credit among landless labour households in two villages of Haryana. In Dhamar village, their survey, which was conducted in 2002, covered 163 landless manual labour households. In Birdhana, a larger multi-caste village, their survey covered 282 households (this included households living in the village settlements and those that lived on the fields) and was conducted in June 2003.
60
The last case study is from northern Kerala. R. Ramakumar conducted a survey in 2001 of all landless households whose participated in agricultural work in Morazha village (Ramakumar 2004). Morazha belongs to a region that was characterised by widespread and acute indebtedness among the peasantry during the British period. It is also a region where there were major struggles against British rule and against landlordism, and where the cooperative movement took strong roots. These village studies present some striking observations with respect to rural credit in the liberalization phase. First, all the village studies report high levels of indebtedness: 64 per cent of households in Morazha were indebted, the corresponding proportions were 66 per cent in Gokilapuram, 72 per cent in Baghra, 75 per cent in Dhamar and 83 per cent in Panahar and Muidara. Secondly, with one exception, the village data combined with information on the banking sector indicate that the share of formal sources of credit, that is, commercial banks, regional rural banks and cooperatives, is extremely low. In Baghra village, for example, only 28 per cent of total credit was from the formal sector. In Panahar and Muidara, the formal sector ed for 24 per cent of credit among all village households in 1995-96 but its share was nil among landless households. In Gokilapuram, formal sources of credit ed for 14 per cent of loans taken and 40 per cent of the principal borrowed by all village households. Class further differentiates access to credit. Among landless hired labour households in Gokilapuram, the formal sector ed for only 22 per cent of total principal borrowed. Surprisingly, in the relatively advanced agricultural state of Haryana, landless labour households continued to depend on informal sources of credit. Of total credit outstanding among landless households, formal sources ed for 12 per cent in Dhamar and 8 per cent among manual labour households living in fields in Birdhana. In Udaipur village, somewhat paradoxically, it was observed that the formal sector ed for 80 per cent of total principal borrowed. Given the limited scale of borrowing, this observation may be explained by the poverty of the village and the absence of informal lenders.
61
The exception is the village of Morazha, where the cooperative movement is well established and where cooperative banks and societies are almost the sole source of credit for rural households. In 2001, 98 per cent of the principal borrowed by landless households was from cooperatives. Even here, though, cooperatives mainly met the needs of consumption credit and the issue of credit to landless households for productive purposes remained neglected. A most striking feature of the village data from Jharkhand was that the people at large had no access to the formal sector of credit. In Baghra, only seven households received any formal sector credit at all in the five years prior to the survey. In each of the two study villages, only one household received any formal-sector credit in the year preceding the survey (Ramachandran and Surjit, 2004). The formal sector had virtually washed its hands of any responsibility to the villages. Thirdly, the two studies that capture changes over time show a clear decline in access to formal sources of credit, particularly credit from scheduled commercial banks, in recent years. In Panahar and Muidara, the share of the formal sector in total debt fell from 24 per cent in 1995-96 to 7 per cent in 2001-02. In Gokilapuram, the share of the formal sector in the total principal borrowed by landless households fell from 80 per cent to 17 per cent between 1985 and 1999. It is worth noting that among landless labour households in Gokilapuram the share of principal borrowed for productive purposes fell from 44 per cent in 1985 to 14 per cent in 1999. Borrowing for consumption purposes dominated the loan portfolio of almost all classes of households. In the study villages in West Bengal and Tamil Nadu, informal lenders are thriving and in fact gained ground after 1991 as a result of the withdrawal of the banking sector from rural areas. The village studies also indicate the gross inadequacy of credit, especially for crop cultivation and other productive activities. The growing and unmet demand for credit, both for direct production as well as for demands of health, education, and other needs, is resulting in what S. L. Shetty “credit starvation” among rural households.
62
This picture is confirmed by the latest report of the Rural Labour Enquiry, which shows both the weakening of banks in rural areas as well as the consolidation of moneylenders. In 1983, the formal sector, comprising government, cooperatives and banks ed for 44 per cent of the debt of agricultural labour households. The share of the formal sector fell to 36 per cent in 1993 and further to 31 per cent in 1999-2000 (GOI, 2004). Over the same period, the share of moneylenders in the total debt incurred by agricultural labour households went up from 18.6 per cent in 1983 to 34 per cent in 1999-2000. During the period when the share of formal credit in total debt of rural households fell, the share of debt taken for productive purposes also fell sharply, from 41 per cent in 1983 to 21.5 per cent in 1999-2000. Despite over three decades of systematic expansion of the banking infrastructure in the country, the village studies indicate that informal sources of credit – including usurious moneylenders -- remain important, and often dominant and growing, sources of credit for rural households. In Panahar and Muidara, trader-moneylenders have come to dominate the informal credit market. In 1995-96, 32 per cent of the total principal borrowed by the surveyed households was borrowed from traders. Moneylenders ed for 17 per cent of the total principal borrowed by households. In 2001-02, of the total principal borrowed by surveyed households, 50 per cent was advanced by agricultural traders and another 31 per cent was advanced by urban businessmen.
In Gokilapuram in 1977, of the total principal borrowed by landless labour households, 27 per cent was advanced by moneylenders and 23 per cent by landowners. By 1999, the share of landowners had fallen to 2.4, per cent while moneylenders ed for 42 per cent. A major finding of this study is the phenomenal rise in the number of moneylenders, full time and part-time, village-based and town-based, operating in the area. In Baghra village too, among informal lenders, moneylenders dominated, ing for 64 per cent of the total principal borrowed by households. The corresponding proportion in Udaipur was 46 per cent.
63
Landowner-employers were the dominant sources of credit for landless workers in Haryana. In Dhamar village, nearly 49 per cent of the total principal borrowed by landless households came from their agricultural employers. The rates of interest on loans from the informal sector, particularly from moneylenders, remain very high. In Panahar and Muidara, where traders were the major source of credit, explicit interest rates were not easy to unearth or compute though rates between 36 and 120 per cent per annum were reported. In Baghra, the modal interest rate range was 48-60 per cent per annum. In Gokilapuram, the modal interest rate range was 60-120 per cent for landless households and 36-48 per cent for all households. Among landless labour households in Gokilapuram, the share of principal borrowed at rates higher than 36 per cent per annum doubled between 1977 and 1999. In Dhamar, the modal rate of interest charged by employer-lenders was 36 per cent per annum. A distinctive feature of the Haryana villages was that the dependence of landless manual worker households on their employers for credit, together with conditions of severe unemployment, forced workers to enter into unfree labour relationships with their creditor-employers. It is particularly noteworthy that unfree labour relationships in these villages coexisted with significant technological advance and commercialisation in agriculture. The study found that, while unfreedom was widespread, there were considerable variations in its specific forms. The nature of unfreedom was closely linked to the high degree of concentration of ownership of land holdings in these villages. Casual workers were subject to various kinds of coercion by employer-creditors, and had also to perform various kinds of labour services. Siri workers in Dhamar village worked under conditions that were akin to bondage. They were not allowed to work for employers other than their creditors and restrictions were often imposed even on their physical mobility. In short, the study found that the dependence of manual workers households on employers for credit was an important factor in sustaining unfree conditions of employment.
64
INSTITUTIONAL CREDIT FOR RURAL INDIA
65
INSTITUTIONAL CREDIT FOR RURAL INDIA In April-May 2004, the Indian electorate delivered a dramatic judgement on economic policy. Thirteen years of neoliberal economic policy (further intensified in the last five to six years) had taken their toll, and there is general agreement among serious political observers that the election results represented widespread protest, rural and urban, against the collapse of livelihoods among the mass of the people. If policy is to repair the damage done to the rural economy, India needs large-scale public investment in the countryside. The links between rural distress and the near-collapse of the formal sector of bank is well recognised, and it is no surprise that one of the promises of the new Government was that it would double the flow of rural credit in three years. The purpose of this essay is not to evaluate the rural credit policy of the United Progressive Alliance government.
Nevertheless, it is clear that if any
government is seriously to address the crisis in rural banking, it must reaffirm the commitment of the state to the policy of social and development banking, and reaffirm the part played by the credit system in redistribution and poverty alleviation. Commercial banks, Regional Rural Banks and cooperatives must lead rural credit revival, which is too serious and large-scale a task to be left merely to self help groups or NGO-controlled private-sector micro-credit organisations. The geographical and functional reach of public sector banking must be restored and extended, differential interest policies reinstated, and special loans-cumsubsidy schemes reintroduced on a large scale for all landless and poor and middle peasant households, scheduled caste and tribe households and other vulnerable sections of the rural population. Priority sector norms must be enforced, and, instead of an alternative such as investment in RIDF bonds, penalties must be imposed on any failure of banks to meet these public-interest targets.
If financial liberalization had the effect of damaging the system of formal credit severely, our case studies show that changes in national banking policy have had a rapid, drastic and potentially disastrous effect on the debt portfolios of the income-poor. In general, as formal sector credit withdrew, the informal sector rushed in to occupy the space that it had vacated. Although it is clear that chronic indebtedness among the rural poor is a problem that cannot be solved by banking policy alone, and that the abolition 66
of usury requires agrarian reform, a decisive change in banking policy is essential for the very survival of the working people in rural India.
Regional Rural Banks Regional Rural Banks, as we have noted, were created in the 1970s exclusively to serve the credit needs of rural India, and specifically those individuals, social groups and regions most excluded by the formal system of credit. For all their weaknesses, these banks ed an important international test. A cross-country study of rural credit institutions threw up the important finding that, in the period 1988-1992, of all the institutions studied, Regional Rural Banks in India incurred the lowest costs of istration, 8.1 per cent of the total portfolio. An important feature of banking reforms has been to alter the equation between different sectors of banking, in this case, to make the norms governing Regional Rural Banks indistinguishable from those governing commercial banks, thus undermining their capacity to serve the special needs of the rural economy and the rural poor There has been a ban on recruitment to the staff of Regional Rural Banks since 1992 (Jagan Mohan, 2004). At every discussion or seminar on problems of rural credit that we have attended in the recent past, bank officials speak of the impact on rural credit of the greying of bank personnel and the thinning of their ranks. Field officers of Regional Rural Banks in the 1970s and 1980s were relatively young and capable of spending substantial periods of time in the villages served by their branches. Regional Rural Banks have also suffered because they are no longer permitted to recruit agricultural science and engineering graduates for specialised lending (see Shetty, 2004 and Jagan Mohan, 2004). Liberalization has had the effect of crippling Regional Rural Banks, rendering them incapable of fulfilling their original mandate.
Marketing of Rural banking in India
67
68
MAJOR RURAL BANKING PLAYERS IN INDIA
69
MAJOR RURAL BANKING PLAYERS IN INDIA REGIONAL RURAL BANKS The Narasimham committee on rural credit recommended the establishment of Regional Rural Banks (RRBs) on the ground that they would be much better suited than the commercial banks or co-operative banks in meeting the needs of rural areas. Accepting the recommendations of the Narasimham committee, the government ed the Regional Rural Banks Act, 1976. A significant development in the field of banking during 1976 was the establishment of 19 Regional Rural Banks (RRBs) under the Regional Rural Banks Act‚1976. The RRBs were established “with a view to developing the rural economy by providing, for the purpose of development of agriculture, trade, commerce, industry and other productive activities in the rural areas, credit and other facilities, particularly to small and marginal farmers, agricultural labourers, artisans and small entrepreneurs, and for matters connected therewith and incidental thereto” .
Objective
Functions
Regional Rural Banks in India
Regional Rural Banks in Tamil Nadu
RRBs established with the explicit objective of
Bridging the credit gap in rural areas
Check the outflow of rural deposits to urban areas
Reduce regional imbalances and increase rural employment generation
The main objectives of setting up the RRB are to provide credit and other facilities‚ especially to the small and marginal farmers‚ agricultural labourers artisans and small entrepreneurs in rural areas.
70
Each RRB will operate within the local limits specified by notification. If necessary‚ a RRB will also establish branches or agencies at places notified by the Government. Each RRB is sponsored by a public sector bank‚ which provides assistance in several ways‚ viz., subscription to its share capital‚ provision of such managerial and financial assistance as may be mutually agreed upon and help the recruitment and training of personnel during the initial period of its functioning. Functions Every RRB is authorized to carry on to transact the business of banking as defined in the Banking Regulation Act and may also engage in other business specified in Section 6 (1) of the said Act. In particular‚ a RRB is required to undertake the business of (a) granting loans and advances to small and marginal farmers and agricultural laborers‚ whether individually or in groups, and to cooperative societies‚ including agricultural marketing societies‚ agricultural processing societies‚ cooperative farming societies‚ primary agricultural credit societies or farmers’ service societies‚ primary agricultural purposes or agricultural operations or other related purposes, and (b) Granting loans and advances to artisans‚ small entrepreneurs and persons of small means engaged in trade‚ commerce‚ industry or other productive activities‚ within its area of operation. The Reserve Bank of India has brought RRB’s under the ambit of priority sector lending on par with the commercial banks. They have to ensure that forty percent of their advances are ed for the priority sector. Within the 40% priority target, 25% should go to weaker section or 10% of their total advances to go to weaker section. Regional Rural Banks in India The State Bank of India is one of the major commercial banks having regional rural banks. There are 30 Regional Rural Banks in India, under the State Bank of India and it is spread in 13 states across India. The number of branches the SBI Regional Rural Banks is more than 71
2000. Several other banks, apart from the State Bank of India also functions as the promoter of rural development in India. List of Regional Rural Banks in India There are a number of regional rural banks in India. Following are the state-wise list of Indian regional rural banks. Andhra Pradesh
Andhra Pradesh Grameena Vikas Bank
Andhra Pragathi Grameena Bank
Deccan Grameena Bank
Chaitanya Godavari Grameena Bank
Saptagiri Grameena Bank
Arunachal Pradesh
Arunachal Pradesh Rural Bank
Assam
Assam Gramin Vikash Bank
Langpi Dehangi Rural Bank
Bihar
Madhya Bihar Gramin Bank
Bihar Kshetriya Gramin Bank 72
Uttar Bihar Kshetriya Gramin Bank
Kosi Kshetriya Gramin Bank
Samastipur Kshetriya Gramin Bank
Chhattisgarh
Chhattisgarh Gramin Bank
Surguja Kshetriya Gramin Bank
Durg-Rajnandgaon Gramin Bank
Gujarat
Dena Gujarat Gramin Bank
Baroda Gujarat Gramin Bank
Saurashtra Gramin Bank
Haryana
Harayana Gramin Bank
Gurgaon Gramin Bank
Himachal Pradesh
Himachal Gramin Bank
Parvatiya Gramin Bank
Jammu & Kashmir
Jammu Rural Bank
73
Ellaquai Dehati Bank
Kamraz Rural Bank
Jharkhand
Jharkhand Gramin Bank
Vananchal Gramin Bank
Karnataka
Karnataka Vikas Grameena Bank
Pragathi Gramin Bank
Cauvery Kalpatharu Grameena Bank
Krishna Grameena Bank
Chimagalur-Kodagu Grameena Bank
Visveshvaraya Gramin Bank
Kerala
Narmada Malwa Gramin Bank
North Malabar Gramin Bank
Madhya Pradesh
Narmada Malwa Gramin Bank
Satpura Kshetriya Gramin Bank
Madhya Bharath Gramin Bank 74
Chambal-Gwalior Kshetriya Gramin Bank
Rewa-Sidhi Gramin Bank
Sharda Gramin Bank
Ratlam-Mandsaur Kshetriya Gramin Bank
Vidisha Bhopal Kshetriya Gramin Bank
Mahakaushal Kshetriya Gramin Bank
Jhabua Dhar Kshetriya Gramin Bank
Maharashtra
Marathwada Gramin Bank
Aurangabad-Jalna Gramin Bank
Wainganga Kshetriya Gramin Bank
Vidharbha Kshetriya Gramin Bank
Solapur Gramin Bank
Thane Gramin Bank
Ratnagiri-Sindhudurg Gramin Bank
Manipur
Manipur Rural Bank
Meghalaya
Ka Bank Nogkyndong Ri Khasi-Jaintia 75
Mizoram
Mizoram Rural Bank
Nagaland
Nagaland Rural Bank
Orissa
Kalinga Gramya Bank
Utkal Gramya Bank
Baitarani Gramya Bank
Neelachal Gramya Bank
Rushikulya Gramya Bank
Punjab
Punjab Gramin Bank
Faridkot-Bhatinda Kshetriya Gramin Bank
Malwa Gramin Bank
Rajasthan
Baroda Rajasthan Gramin Bank
Marwar Ganganagar Bikaner Gramin Bank
Rajasthan Gramin Bank
Jaipur Thar Gramin Bank
76
Hodoti Kshetriya Gramin Bank
Mewar Anchalik Gramin Bank
Tamil Nadu
Pandyan Grama Bank
Pallavan Grama Bank
Tripura
Tripura Gramin Bank
Uttar Pradesh
Purvanchal Gramin Bank
Kashi Gomti Samyut Gramin Bank
Uttar Pradesh Gramin Bank
Shreyas Gramin Bank
Lucknow Kshetriya Gramin Bank
Ballia Kshetriya Gramin Bank
Triveni Kshetriya Gramin Bank
Aryavart Gramin Bank
Kisan Gramin Bank
Kshetriya Kisan Gramin Bank
Etawah Kshetriya Gramin Bank 77
Rani Laxmi Bai Kshetriya Gramin Bank
Baroda Western Uttar Pradesh Gramin Bank
Devipatan Kshetriya Gramin Bank
Prathama Bank
Baroda Eastern Uttar Pradesh Gramin Bank
Uttaranchal
Uttaranchal Gramin Bank
Nainital Almora Kshetriya Gramin Bank
West Bengal
Bangiya Gramin Vikash Bank
Paschim Banga Gramin Bank
Uttar Banga Kshetriya Gramin Bank
The other Regional Rural Banks in India are -
Haryana State Cooperative Apex Bank Limited The main purpose of the Haryana State Cooperative Apex Bank Limited is to financially assist the artisans in the rural areas, farmers and agrarian unskilled labor, and the small rural entrepreneurs of Haryana. Haryana State Cooperative Apex Bank Limited also referred as the HARCOBANK, is one of the apex organizations in the state of Haryana. The HARCOBANK holds a special economic position in the state of Haryana. The Haryana State Cooperative Apex Bank Limited offers several types of financial assistances to the individuals. The financial aids include credit for the promotion of agriculture, non-agrarian credit, and bank 78
deposit facilities. The HARCOBANK have been functioning as an investor for more than three decades.
National Bank for Agriculture and Rural Development The main purpose of the National Bank for Agriculture and Rural Development is to provide credit for the development and publicity of small scaled industries, handicrafts, rural crafts, village industries, cottage industries, agriculture, etc. The NABARD also s all other related economic operations in the rural sector, promotion of sustainable growth in the rural sector. The NABARD also plays the role of a contributor to the rural development by the means of promoting institutional development, facilitating refinance to loan providers in the rural sector, inspection, monitoring, and evaluation of client financial corporations. National Bank for Agriculture and Rural Development (NABARD) was established as the premiere rural development bank.
Sindhanur Urban Souharda Co-operative Bank The main purpose of the Sindhanur Urban Souharda Co-operative Bank is to provide financial to the rural sector. The Sindhanur Urban Souharda Co-operative Bank is more commonly known as the SUCO Bank.
79
United Bank of India The role played by the United Bank of India (UBI) as one of the regional rural banks is phenomenal. The UBI has propagated the network of branches in order to actively take part in the rural improvement and development. Syndicate Bank The Syndicate Bank has it grass roots in the rural sector. The development of the Syndicate Bank was in accordance to the development of the banking sector in India and. The Syndicate Bank has performed actively in the development of the rural sector in India. The Regional Rural Banks in India has actively contributed to the growth of the rural sector. The growth of the rural industries in India and the development of the rural business and economy have been dependent largely on the investment and financial aids provided by the Regional Rural Banks in India. Regional Rural Banks in Tamil Nadu Indian Bank has sponsored two Regional Rural Banks (RRBs) viz., Saptagiri Grameena Bank and Pallavan Grama Bank. Pallavan Grama Bank with Head Quarters at Salem is operating in 14 districts of Tamil Nadu viz., Salem, Namakkal, Krishnagiri, Dharmapuri, Villupuram, Cuddalore, Coimbatore, Karur,
Erode,
Nilgiris,
Vellore,
Tiruvannamalai,
Kancheepuram
and
Tiruvallur.
The third RRB sponsored by Indian Bank is Puduvai Bharathiar Grama Bank at Union Territory of Puducherry with its head quarters at Puducherry.
80
Parameter
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
Growth(%)
No. Of RRBs
196
196
196
196
196
196
196
96
86
86
83
Capital
1380
1959
2049
2143
2141
2221
25354
48488
58990
67855
76392
5435.65
Deposit
27059
32226
39294
44539
49582
56295
69719
83143
99093
120184
124296
359.35
6680
7760
8800
9471
17138
21286
33486
45666
48559
62629
96699
1347.5
10559
12427
15050
17710
20934
25038
32692
40345
43456
46678
51283
385.62
35820
42236
49596
56802
62500
70195
436805
803416
844982
898760
984364
2648.3
3281
3938
4619
5191
5391
5535
6041
6547
7729
7586
8786
165.94
151
207
240
370
430
697
743
790
873
853
1023
577.4
3432
4145
4859
5561
5821
6231
6784
7337
7602
8421
9809
185.8
Investment Advance Total Assets Interest Earned Other Income Total Income
81
Interest expanded 2131
2565
2966
3329
3340
3363
5902
8441
8860
8362
9260
334.5
982
1056
1165
1459
1667
1825
1958
2092
22134
2345
2598
164.6
99
96
128
163
132
289
329
369
434
590
699
606.3
3113
3621
4130
4787
5107
5187
7860
10533
10994
10707
11758
277.7
319
319
729
774
714
1044
985
926
1383
1859
1987
522.8
Operating Expanses
Provision And Contigencies
Total Expenses Operating Profit
82
RRBS – IMPORTANT BANKING INDICATORS
83
OBJECTIVE OF THE STUDY 84
OBJECTIVE OF THE STUDY 1. To study marketing of rural banking in India. 2. To study comparative marketing of rural and urban banking in India. 3. To study about Institutional sources consist of the co-operative and commercial banks including Regional Rural Banks (RRBS) 4. To study about Non institutional or private sources including money lender traders commission agents and landlords
85
RESEARCH METHODOLOGY
86
RESEARCH METHODOLOGY Research in common parlance refers to a search for knowledge. The advanced learner’s dictionary of current English lays down the meaning of research as “a careful investigation of enquiry especially through search for new facts in any branch of knowledge.” The systematic approach concerning generalization and the formulation of a theory is also research. The purpose of research is to discover answers to questions through the application of scientific procedures.
“A research design is the arrangement of conditions for collection and analysis of data in a manner that aims to combine relevance to the research purpose with economy in procedure.” - JOHN.W.BEST Research may be defined as “any organized inquiry designed and carried out to provide information for solving a problem”. - EMORY “Research is essentially an investigation, a recording and an analysis of evidence for the purpose of gaining knowledge”. - ROBERT ROSS
DESCRIPTIVE RESEARCH DESIGN Descriptive research design studies are those studies, which are concerned with describing the character of a group. The researcher makes a plan of the study his research work. That will enable the researcher to save and resources such a plan of study or blue print or study is called a research design. Three main purposes of research are to describe, explain, and validate findings. Description emerges following creative exploration, and serves to organize the findings in order to fit them with explanations, and then test or validate those explanations The reason to adopt the descriptive research is due to the type of research question, design, and data analysis that will be applied to a given topic. Descriptive statistics tell what is, while inferential statistics try to determine cause and effect. Descriptive research aims at fact finding & more often is based on surveys .It’s purpose to describe the present state of affairs of the topic of study. It is more focused than an exploratory study. It provides basic information for formulating more sophisticated study.
87
DATA COLLECTION The study was based on questionnaire method. There are two types of data collection:
Primary data
Secondary data
Primary data The primary data are those, which are collected a fresh and for the first time happen to be original in character. It has been collected through a Questionnaire and personal interview. Only the primary data is not the sufficient to get information about the complete topic so both primary and secondary data is collected.
Secondary data Secondary data are those which have already been collected by someone else and which have already been ed through the stratified process. It has collected through the books, journals & Internet.
RESEARCH INSTRUMENT Questionnaire “A questionnaire is simply a set of questions designed to generate the data necessary for accomplishing a research project’s objectives” (Parasuraman, 1991, p.363).
SAMPLE DESIGN: POPULATION It covers the 100 unit of population.
SAMPLE PROCEDURES In this study convenient sampling method was adopted. First each organization was divided into different departments like Operations, Customer Services, Human Resources, Internet Marketing and under writing 88
departments. From this department, the respondents were selected on the basis of convenience.
INTERVEIW SCHEDULE
The interview schedule has been used to collect the data. Information can be gathered even when the respondents happen to be literate or illiterate.
TABULATION
It is the arrangement of classified data in an orderly manner. This involves creating table for recording the filled in interview schedule. These tables are of immense help to analysis by using the statistics tools help to analysis by using the statistical tools.
TOOLS USED FOR ANALYSIS
Simple percentage analysis It is simple analysis tool. In this method, based on the opinions of the respondents, percentage and bar chart is calculated for the respective scales of each factor.
Formula: Simple percentage =
No of Respondents
x 100
Total No of Sample Size
89
LIMITATIONS OF THE STUDY The study is focused only in Bajaj Allianz Life Insurance Company. Thus the respondents are not come forward to provide their regarding their organization than the result is bias. In this study the sample size is 70. The result might vary when the sample size values changes it. Researcher fined the difficulty in searching the appropriate advisor and respondent throughout the city. The research was limited to the Bhopal city.
90
DATA ANALYSIS AND INTERPRETATION
91
DATA ANALYSIS AND INTERPRETATION 1) Central Scheme to provide Interest Subsidy for the period of moratorium on loans taken by farmer from economically weaker sections from schedule banks under the loan scheme of the Indian Banks Association? □ To great extent □ To some extent □ To very little extent Table: 1:- % of the respondent Rural Bank
Urban Bank
To great extent
64
0
To some extent
26
72
To very little extent
10
28
total
100
100%
72
80 70
64
60 50 40
28
26
30 20
10
10 0
To great extent 0
To some extent Rural Bank
To very little extent
Urban Bank
92
Interpretation: From the above data it is evident that among the respondent, 44% of the respondent of rural bank says that Central Scheme to provide Interest Subsidy for the period of moratorium on loans taken by farmer from economically weaker sections from schedule banks under the loan scheme of the Indian Banks Association to great extend where as none of the respondent of Urban Bank says that Central Scheme to provide Interest Subsidy for the period of moratorium on loans taken by farmer from economically weaker sections from schedule banks under the loan scheme of the Indian Banks Association to great extend. 26% of the respondent of rural bank says that Central Scheme to provide Interest Subsidy for the period of moratorium on loans taken by farmer from economically weaker sections from schedule banks under the loan scheme of the Indian Banks Association to great extend where as 72% of the respondent of Urban Bank says that Central Scheme to provide Interest Subsidy for the period of moratorium on loans taken by farmer from economically weaker sections from schedule banks under the loan scheme of the Indian Banks Association to some extend. 10% of the respondent of rural bank says that Central Scheme to provide Interest Subsidy for the period of moratorium on loans taken by farmer from economically weaker sections from schedule banks under the loan scheme of the Indian Banks Association to great extend to very little great extend where as 28% of the respondent of Urban Bank says that Central Scheme to provide Interest Subsidy for the period of moratorium on loans taken by farmer from economically weaker sections from schedule banks under the loan scheme of the Indian Banks Association to very little extend.
93
2) To what extent is Sales Promotions have been used by banker to increase sales in the short term? □ Completely □ Partially □ Nil Table: 02% of the respondent Rural Bank
Urban Bank
Completely
90
59
Partially
10
30
Nil
0
11
total
100
100%
90 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0
59
30 11
10
Completely
Partially Rural Bank
0 Nill
Urban Bank
94
Interpretation: From the above data it is evident that among the respondent, 90% of the respondent of Rural Bank says that Sales Promotions have been used by banker to increase sales in the short term where as 59% of the respondent of Urban Bank says that Sales Promotions have been used by banker to increase sales in the short term. 10% of the respondent of rural bank says that Sales Promotions have been used by banker to increase sales in the short term where as 30% of the respondent of Urban Bank says that Sales Promotions have been used by banker to increase sales in the short term. No respondent of rural bank says that Sales Promotions have been used by banker to increase sales in the short term is nill where as 11% of the respondent of Urban Bank says that Sales Promotions have been used by banker to increase sales in the short term is nill.
95
3) Does your marketing policy of bank have a focus marketing on agro- sector? □ Strongly agree □ Agree □ Disagree □ Strongly disagree □ Can’t say Table: 3% of the respondent
Rural Bank
Urban Bank
Strongly Agree
83
61
Agree
17
23
Disagree
0
16
strongly disagree
0
0
Can't say
0
0
100
100%
total
90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0
83 61
17
23
16 0
Rural Bank
0
0
0
0
Urban Bank
96
Interpretation: From the above data it is evident that among the respondent, 83% of the respondent of Rural Bank strongly agree that Marketing policy of bank have a focus marketing on agro- sector where as 61% of the respondent of Urban Bank also strongly agrees that Marketing policy of bank have a focus marketing on agro- sector. 17% of the respondent of Rural Bank agree that Marketing policy of bank have a focus marketing on agro- sector where as 23% of the respondent of Urban Bank also agrees that Marketing policy of bank have a focus marketing on agro- sector. None of the respondent of Rural Bank disagree that Marketing policy of bank have a focus marketing on agro- sector where as 16% of the respondent of Urban Bank also disagree that Marketing policy of bank have a focus marketing on agro- sector. None of the respondent of Rural Bank & Urban Bank also strongly disagree that Marketing policy of bank have a focus marketing on agro- sector. None of the respondent of Rural Bank & Urban Bank can’t says that Marketing policy of bank have a focus marketing on agro- sector.
97
4) Multiple ‘basic’ financial services and loan gateway is product marketing of the bank? □ Yes
□ No
Table: 4:-% of the respondent Rural Bank
Urban Bank
Yes
87
62
No
13
38
total
100
100%
100
87 62
80 60
38
40
13
20 0
Yes
No Rural Bank
Urban Bank
Interpretation: From the above data it is evident that among the respondent, 87% of the respondent of Rural Bank
says that Multiple ‘ basic’ financial services
and loan gateway is product marketing of the bank where as 62% of the respondent of Urban Bank also says that Multiple ‘ basic’ financial services and loan gateway is product marketing of the bank. 13% of the respondent of Rural Bank sasys that Multiple ‘ basic’ financial services and loan gateway is product marketing of the bank where as 38% of the respondent of Urban Bank also says that Multiple ‘ basic’ financial services and loan gateway is product marketing of the bank.
98
5) Devised to ensure usage as well as profitability Quantity discounts, and ease in payment modes is pricing marketing of the bank. □ Yes
□ No
Table: 5:-% of the respondent Rural Bank
Urban Bank
Yes
11
13
No
89
87
total
100
100%
89
100
87
80 60 40
13
11
20 0
Yes
No Rural Bank
Urban Bank
Interpretation: From the above data it is evident that among the respondent, 11% of the respondent of rural bank says that Devised to ensure usage as well as profitability Quantity discounts, and ease in payment modes is pricing marketing of the bank. whereas 13% of the respondent of Urban Bank also says that Devised to ensure usage as well as profitability Quantity discounts, and ease in payment modes is pricing marketing of the bank.. 89% of the respondent of rural bank says that Devised to ensure usage as well as profitability Quantity discounts, and ease in payment modes is pricing marketing of the bank. whereas 87% of the respondent of Urban Bank also says that Devised to ensure usage as well as profitability Quantity discounts, and ease in payment modes is pricing marketing of the bank.. 99
6) Comprehensive offering of different services is placement marketing of the bank? □ Traditional
□ Modern
Table: 6:-% of the respondent
Rural Bank
Urban Bank
Traditional
98
91
modern
2
9
100
100%
total 98
91
100 80 60 40 2
20 0
Traditional Rural Bank
9
modern Urban Bank
Interpretation: From the above data it is evident that among the respondent, 98% of the respondent of rural bank says that Comprehensive offering of different services is placement marketing of the bank where as 91% of the respondent of Urban Bank says that Comprehensive offering of different services is placement marketing of the bank. 2 % of the respondent of rural bank says that Comprehensive offering of different services is placement marketing of the bank where as 9% of the respondent of Urban Bank says that Comprehensive offering of different services is placement marketing of the bank.
100
7) Collaborating with NGO’s to development Knowledge marketing of the bank □ Yes
□ No
Table: 7:-% of the respondent
Rural Bank
Urban Bank
Yes
33
81
No
67
19
total
100
100%
81
90 80
67
70 60 50
33
40
19
30 20 10 0
Rural Bank
Urban Bank Yes
No
Interpretation: From the above data it is evident that among the respondent, 33% of the respondent of RURAL BANK
says that Collaborating with NGO’s to
development Knowledge marketing of the bank where as 81% of the respondent of Urban Bank also says that Collaborating with NGO’s to development Knowledge marketing of the bank. 67% of the respondent of RURAL BANK
says that Collaborating with NGO’s to
development Knowledge marketing of the bankwhere as 19% of the respondent of
101
Urban Bank says Collaborating with NGO’s to development Knowledge marketing of the bank.
102
CONCLUSION
103
CONCLUSION RRBs' performance in respect of some important indicators was certainly better than that of commercial banks or even cooperatives. RRBs have also performed better in of providing loans to small and retail traders and petty non-farm rural activities. In recent years, they have taken a leading role in financing Self-Help Groups (SHGs) and other micro-credit institutions and linking such groups with the formal credit sector. RRBs should really be strengthened and provided with more resources with which they can undertake more of these important activities. And most certainly they should be kept apart from a profit-oriented corporate motivation that would reduce their capacity to provide much needed financial services to the rural areas, including to agriculture. Ideally, the best use of the resources raised by RRBs through deposits would be through extensive crosssubsidisation. This, in turn, really requires an apex body that would cover and oversee all the RRBs, something like a National Rural Bank of India (NRBI). The number of rural branches should be increased rather than reduced; they should be encouraged to develop more sophisticated methods of credit delivery to meet the changing needs of farming; and most of all, there should be greater coordination between district planning authorities, Panchayati raj institutions and the banks operating in rural areas. Only then will the RRBs fulfill the promise that is so essential for rural development.
104
BIBLIOGRAPHY Books:
Aaker (1991) Building Strong Brands; New York: Free Press
Chatterjee, Jauchius, Kaas and Satpathy no. 1, (2002): 'Revving up auto branding', McKinsey Quarterly.
David. A. Aaker, V.Kumar & George S. Day, (2001) Descriptive Research: Marketing Research, Seventh Edition, pp 17
Saxena, Rajan. (2003):’Marketing Management’ Tata Mcgraw-Hill Publishing Company Limited. New Delhi Sontakki, C.N. (1997):’Marketing Management’ Kayali Publisher., New Delhi. Kotler, Philip. (1999):’Marketing Management’ Prentice Hall Of India Pvt. Ltd., New Delhi. Kothari, C.R (2001):’Research Methodology’, Vishwa Publication., New Delhi Sharma,D.D(2002):’Marketing Research’,Sultan Chand Sons, New Delhi
Magazines:
Business Today
Business Week.
Business World
Newspapers
Economic Times
The Hindu
Times of India
105
Annexure QUESTIONNAIRE 1) Central Scheme to provide Interest Subsidy for the period of moratorium on loans taken by farmer from economically weaker sections from schedule banks under the loan scheme of the Indian Banks Association? □ To great extent □ To some extent □ To very little extent 2) To what extent is Sales Promotions have been used by banker to increase sales in the short term? □ Completely □ Partially □ Nil 3) Does your marketing policy of bank have focus marketing on agro- sector? □ Strongly agree □ Agree □ Disagree □ Strongly disagree □ Can’t say 4) Multiple ‘ basic’ financial services and loan gateway is product marketing of the bank?
□ Yes
□ No
5) Devised to ensure usage as well as profitability Quantity discounts, and ease in payment modes is pricing marketing of the bank.? 106
□ Yes
□ No
6) Comprehensive offering of different services is placement marketing of the bank? □ Traditional
□ Modern
7) Collaborating with NGO’s to development Knowledge marketing of the bank
□ Yes
□ No
107